7. Conclusions and Recommendations
The above analysis provides ground for conclusions and recommendations, addressed to the Bulgarian government, the professionals, the public opinion, the EU institutions, and the EU member countries. In each of the preceding sections the analysis was followed by conclusions and a number of recommendations, The most important are summarized below:
1. Strategy for Economic and Social Development of Bulgaria
Accession to the EU is a strategic objective for Bulgaria. The criteria and the standards that should be met are known. Equally obvious is that it is impossible within ten years to comply with the standards of the Union. The most important policies and instruments Bulgaria should apply during the preparation for accession are more or less clear. The pre-accession economic policy must gradually converge with the economic policy of the EU member countries. Therefore, the major framework of economic and social objectives (the ends) and the policy instruments (the means) are more or less known.
Within this economic and institutional environment, the elaboration of a National Strategy for Economic and Social Development by 2010 could play a positive role in mobilizing the national energy of Bulgaria and its targeting along the strategic priorities. The main objective of the strategy is to contribute to faster development and therefore – better preparation for accession to the EU. The strategy should comprise intermediate and final objectives along all issues, covered by the accession negotiations and the policies, contributing to their achievement.
The major economic objectives by 2010 are suggested as follows:
The quantitative and qualitative macroeconomic framework of such a Strategy is provided in Table No.8 (Section 2) as well as in the other sections of this analysis.
The strategy should also provide clear commitments for the Government’s medium- and long-term intentions on macroeconomic, social, institutional, and other policies, covering all chapters for accession negotiations. It should also state how policy instruments and regulations would cooperate with market forces, without suppressing them; how economic efficiency will interact with social justice.
The expanded Union will grow in diversity and will be less flexible and efficient in global competition. The EU does not have much chances of success in global competition, particularly with regard to the USA, under present complicated economic and institutional arrangements and growing heterogeneity. Its future chances will be subject to the intensity of intracommunity integration and more vigorous competition. The most advanced EU member countries would hardly accept the speed of integration to be determined by the weaker members, and even less so – by the new members. This would guarantee the failure of the EU in global competition. The most advanced member countries will probably prefer dynamic manoeurability to clumsy monoliths.
Elaborating the Strategy on economic and social development of Bulgaria one must bear in mind the implications of possible adoption of the concept of multyspeed development of the expanded Union. In this case grave economic realities (4-5 fold lower GDP per capita, equally lower competitiveness, productivity, personal incomes, etc.) will certainly place Bulgaria in the lowest speed group. In other words, joining the EU Bulgaria would move from one economic periphery (of divided Europe) to another one (of united Europe).
Accession may change the relative institutional position of Bulgaria, but its economic position will stay the same. The latter may change only if and when Bulgarian economic potential and the level of economic performance increase substantially, namely in 20-30 years, or later.
We recommend to the Government of Bulgaria to entrust a group of most prominent Bulgarian experts with the development of such a strategy by the middle of 2002.
2. Assessment of the Effects of the Bulgarian Integration into the European Union.
As stated in Section 1, the decision at the end of 1999 to invite Bulgaria for accession negotiations was politically motivated. Political considerations have played a major role for extending such invitations to other CEE countries as well. "Nonaccession" of Bulgaria never was and will never be a viable alternative to "accession" for reasons, elaborated above. Political and economic security offered by the EU were a fundamental goal for Bulgaria and the other applicant countries. The achievement of such goal justified any costs. It was also assumed by intuition that benefits from accession prevailed by far over the costs. It was even felt that assessment of such effects was a waste of time.
Accession negotiations have already started, though the most difficult for Bulgaria are to come. The politicians and the professionals should answer the difficult question: how to prepare, so that the gains of accession are the most and the losses - the least?
The answer of this question does not necessarily require an exact accounting balance of the overall positive and negative effects. It necessitates, however, great number (70–80 or more) analyses of the positive and negative effects of specific aspects of integration. Such as joining of the Single Market, Common Agricultural Policy, structural and regional policies, appropriate patterns of financing, accession preparation costs, development of various components of infrastructure and the links between the national systems and the transeuropean ones, the development of nuclear power energy generation and nuclear safety, protection of consumers and their health, development of modern human capital (education, health care and others), economic and social issues of aging, preparation for the challenges of information society as well as of genetic engineering, room for development of national science and research activities, complete liberalization of trade, capital and labour flows, consequences from the brain drain, new aspects of regional policy, comprehensive cost–benefit analysis on each transitional arrangement requested, and many others.
There are no comprehensive analyses and forecasts on these specific issues in Bulgaria. If anything is being done, it is confined to a closed circle of civil servants without involvement of the most prominent independent experts. There are no guarantees that it is sufficient for the forthcoming difficult accession negotiations. To the contrary, there are symptoms that it is not.
The Bulgarian parliament, the professional associations, the public opinion get no information on the progress of negotiations. Everything is veiled in secrecy. Of course, in such important negotiations full publicity is counter productive. Decisions on fundamental issues in total secrecy are even more damaging to the vital national interests.
We recommend to the Bulgarian government to set up and finance a working group, comprising the best experts from the public administration, researchers, independent experts and experts from non-government organizations. The group must prepare a comprehensive assessment of the expected positive and negative effects at macro, micro, regional, sectoral and subsectoral levels of integration during the pre- and post- accession periods. This group should complete the assignment by the middle of 2002. The experience of the Central European (CE) countries should be thoroughly studied.
We recommend to the Governing Board of the Bulgarian Academy of Sciences to readjust the working programmes of the research institutes so as to promote in the best possible way the preparation of Bulgaria for EU accession and support the accession negotiations. One has in mind the institutes of economics, law, sociology, demography, psychology and those from other areas of research. The same is recommended to the Ministry of Education and Science in regard to the education and research activities in the universities.
3. Symmetric Liberalization of Trade, Capital and Labour Flows
In Sections 4.4, 4.5 and 6 we describe the asymmetric liberalization of the integration flows and the implications for the countries involved. Bulgaria and the other applicant countries endure the negative effects of this asymmetry.
We recommend to the Bulgarian government to initiate joint analyses with other CEECs on the consequences of asymmetric liberalization and negotiate adjustments in the on-going unbalanced policy. One should demand at least partial liberalization of the migration regime prior to accession. The liberalization of the labour flows must be symmetric to the trade and the capital flow liberalization after accession.
Within the context of labour flows in Section 4.4 is stated that a large portion of the skilled immigrants from Bulgaria and the other CEECs perform unskilled work in the EU countries. Their stay in these countries under such conditions does not enrich their knowledge and experience. They do not learn enough novelties, which could be transferred to their countries upon return. They may even loose part of the initial skills. Such irrational utilization of skilled labour is wasteful both to the sending and the receiving countries.
The governments of Bulgaria and the other CEECs, jointly with trade unions and business organizations should not be passive observers of this process. Of course, they cannot and should not interfere in the personal decisions of the immigrants, or in the decisions of the employers from the EU countries. They could, however, consider jointly with the European Commission and the governments of the member countries economic, financial, social, institutional and other instruments, creating an appropriate environment to alleviate the wasting of skilled labour.
The skilled labour is educated and trained in the CEECs for many years. It costs these countries hundreds of billions of dollars. Owing to the economic and social crisis in the transition countries and the large income gaps, they are looking for better prospects in the EU countries and elsewhere. Moreover, the EU governments take vigorous action to recruit highly skilled experts, particularly on information technologies, offering them attractive working and living conditions. This will certainly expand over the following years and decades with the deterioration of aging in the EU countries. This new wave of "brain drain" emerges as a powerful instrument for intellectual and economic bleeding of the CEE countries in the foreseeable future.
As stated in Section 6 the problem is more complex than it looks. The issue is not of the "black and white" type. At first glance the "brain drain" is harmful only to the poor countries and beneficial to the rich ones. If these young people remained in Bulgaria they would contribute to its development, but their innovative potential would not develop in its full strength. Bulgaria cannot offer them the indispensable informational, technological, financial, experimental, institutional, and other prerequisites. Only the advance countries can afford it. And, of course, they will extract the benefits. The global science and technology development will also benefit.
The real issue is not the existence of a "brain drain", but how to share the benefits between the sending countries, which grow and educate them and the receiving countries, which develop them further and get all benefits.
The governments of Bulgaria and the other CEE countries neither can nor should try to control or resist the "brain drain". They have, however, sufficient ground to put the issue before the EU and look for appropriate forms of sharing the benefits. The Bulgarian government should initiate consultations among CEE countries and if a consensus was reached – submit a joint proposal to the EU.
4. The Migration Policy of Bulgaria, Related to the "Brain Drain"
In Section 4.4.5 some ideas are shared on the migration policy of Bulgaria with special focus on the "brain drain". It is stated that the policy should be balanced, target–oriented, reciprocal and pragmatic.
The components of such a policy should be developed in greater details, based on the following principles and ideas:
- Bulgaria cannot and must not impose administrative restrictions upon its citizens, who wish to emigrate;
- The Bulgarian migration policy should be balanced, taking into account that migration has both positive and negative consequences;
- Bulgaria is not in a position at present to provide appropriate environment for the realization of all its citizens at home. Therefore, the attention should be focused on those, who could contribute the most to the national development – now and in the future. These are the young talents and the most skilled of all ages. The authorities should help them by providing appropriate conditions for finding jobs in the material and non-material production, research and development and others; higher remuneration; assistance in the acquirement of family housing; involvement in taking important government decisions in their area of competence; establishment of joint facilities with prominent international companies on research, development, production, marketing and financing in Bulgaria, where they could be employed;
- The authorities, along with others should bear the costs for short- and medium- term specialization abroad of skilled Bulgarian experts under specific contractual arrangements;
- The authorities, along with others should bear the costs for participation of skilled Bulgarian experts at international conferences, symposia, fairs, and so on;
- The authorities, along with others should help regular and expedient delivery of the most recent publications and information by Internet and traditional channels;
- The authorities must exempt from taxes, import tariffs and others, research and development activities, aimed at boosting growth, productivity and competitiveness;
- The Board of the Bulgarian Academy of Sciences, the Ministry of Education and Science, the boards of the universities, of other public and private research entities should organize public nationwide discussion on the present situation of Bulgarian science and research and preparation of young researchers. They should also put forward comprehensive proposals to the Government on the public support needed for revitalization of the research and development activities over the coming years.
5. For equipollent trade liberalization and more balanced trade
In Section 4.2. is shown that trade flows between the CEE and the EU were liberalized to a large extent. The only exceptions are the protectionist regime of the EU for agricultural goods and trade with some services. The arrangements made in the middle of 2000 alleviated only partially the problem with agricultural trade. The goods for which Bulgaria and the other CEE countries are relatively competitive (or less uncompetitive) have a difficult access to the EU market. The goods for which CEECs are not competitive or which they do not produce have easy access to the EU market. This trade regime is obviously aimed at protecting the interests of EU producers and suppressing CEE exports to the Community.
Such one-sided trade policy has no meaningful economic foundations. Particularly having in mind that an economic giant like the EU is practicing it with less developed countries, invited for accession negotiations. Such restrictions impede the preparation of these countries for accession. Ultimately, this policy generates problems for the Union in the future, originating from accession of ill prepared new members, for which the Community would be partly to blame.
We recommend to the government of Bulgaria, jointly with the governments of the other CEE countries to prepare an analysis of the losses incurred by the protectionist EU trade regime during the past decade. It should be submitted to the European Commission and to other EU institutions with a proposal for multilateral negotiations on solving the problem.
In Section 4.2 and elsewhere in the analysis is shown that trade between the EU and the CEE is unbalanced. The trade deficit of the CEE is chronic and ever growing for years. The problem will become more acute over the years, particularly for countries such as Bulgaria.
There is no easy solution of this problem. The CEE countries need the investment goods and the modern technologies of the EU countries and are going to import them in even larger quantities in the process of accession preparation. The imports of consumer goods are also growing. The economic consequences of the trade deficits due to imports of capital goods differ from these owing to imports of consumer goods.
The export potential of Bulgaria is and will remain limited in the foreseeable future due to low competitiveness. At the same time imports will be booming. This will boost the trade deficit to (may be) unbearable levels in the medium– and long–term. The question is – how long can the economy afford such a deficit? Apparently, not for too long. In case of serious constraints on the balance of payments, urgent EU support might be needed. If the "unbearability threshold" of trade and payments deficits is reached, this may hamper the trade between the EU and the CEE, with negative implications for both sides.
We recommend to the Bulgarian government to initiate the preparation of a comprehensive analysis and projection of imports from and exports to the EU over the following decade within a framework of a long–term forecast for the balance of payments. The analysis and the projection should cover not only the quantitative foreign trade indicators, but also the competitiveness of Bulgarian exports. Some of these indexes were used in Sections 2.2.2 and 4.2.3. The results from the analysis and the forecast should be used in the accession negotiations on the subjects related to the Single Market as well as for preparation of economic, institutional and other measures to upgrade the pattern of exports and boost its competitiveness. On this ground measures should be proposed which will alleviate (at least partially) the trade deficit with the EU over the following years.
Other candidate countries could take such steps as well. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (WIIW) might also contribute with its comprehensive analyses. This institute might even assume co-ordination of national CEECs studies on this issue.
6. Overcoming the Asymmetry between the EU and the CEECs in the Timing of the Costs and Benefits of Integration.
In Sections 5 and 6 is proven that the EU countries got the bulk of the benefits of the integration during the 90s while the CEE countries were investing for accession preparation. The same pattern of sharing of the costs and benefits is expected during the new decade. Therefore, the EU gets the benefits first, and later on will make the costs as transfers to the applicant countries, and opening of its labour markets. The CEE countries incur first the costs, including the accumulated large trade deficits and will hope for benefits later on over the years as transfers, free access to goods, capital and labour markets of the expanded Union. The ratio in sharing the costs and the benefits may be slightly better for the CE countries, due to their earlier accession, say by 2005.
The EU countries will benefit even more from the integration process in the future. As stated in Section 6.2, Bulgaria and the other CEE countries will carry a major structural, technological, financial, ecological and other modernization over the next two–three decades. The modernization investments will amount to trillions of US dollars. The bulk will be modern equipment, technologies, software, know–how, and will be procured mainly from the EU member countries. This will generate additional growth, exports, jobs, budget revenues, social security system revenues and private incomes for these countries. If there were no accession preparations for the CEECs, this would not have happened. At least, not of this scale!
The implicit consent of the CEE countries with this obvious economic asymmetry is hardly the most rational behavior! Of course, it should be kept in mind that the CEECs are the weaker partner in the negotiations and cannot do much in the absence of good will from the stronger partner. Hopefully, there are a number of politicians and professionals in the EU, who will understand that it will be difficult to uphold such a policy. And would adopt a more balanced one!
We advise the government of Bulgaria to use these arguments in the accession negotiations. Joint actions by the applicant countries, vis-à-vis the European Commission may be even more productive. A solution of the problem should be searched in several directions:
7. Preparation for the Single Market.
In Sections 2., 4.2 and 4.3 is stated that the preparation for participation in the Single Market will be the greatest challenge for Bulgaria. The competitiveness of Bulgarian goods is low. Decades will be neded to narrow the gap in competitiveness between Bulgarian and EU companies. Particularly within the context of limited saving capacities of the Bulgarian economy and the modest transfers from the pre-accession funds. Competitive pressure from the Community will grow stronger after the accession. In addition, it will be the most difficult to obtain transitional arrangements in the Single Market area.
We recommend to the Bulgarian government to initiate the preparation of a thorough analysis of the current situation and a forecast for the costs and benefits of trade and financial integration of Bulgaria into the EU. Both traditional methods and simulating models should be applied in the analysis and the projections.
Top EU officials keep saying that there will be limited transition periods on issues, related to the Internal Market. This is quite reasonable because inflated with numerous transitional arrangements the Single market will no longer be the same. The Market must apply the same rules to all economic agents. Differentiated treatment of the participants destroys the market and the competition. The implications for present and future members and for the Union as a whole will be grave.
With limited financial resources, short pre-accession periods and symbolic transfers from the EU, most of the new members (and certainly Bulgaria) will not be prepared to face the competition on the Single Market and to comply with the EU standards in other areas. This will disturb the functioning of the Market and the expanded Union. The concussions in the ill prepared new members will be more dangerous. Let there is no illusions!
As stated in Section 5 an invitation for accession negotiations may be extended as a gesture of gratitude for political loyalty, but this is not sufficient to face the challenges of the competition on the Internal Market. The political gestures’ language is incomprehensible to the Single Market. A regional European political market is unthinkable at the globalization age on the threshold of the New century. There were attempts to establish a regional political market under Soviet domination – CMEA. The outcome is well known.
Market competition calls for goods and services of dissent quality and reasonable price. The market is not interested whether they come from countries with politically loyal governments. Here is the major difference between an invitation for negotiations (which could be politically motivated), and a decision for accession (which must be based on solid economic foundations, supported by political considerations). The economic implications of the two steps differ fundamentally. And these consequences can not be disregarded!
An accession of politically loyal, but economically ill-prepared country is dangerous for the EU, and even more so for the country concerned. The European Union is not the Council of Europe! Neither NATO! The Single Market (this machine for growth and prosperity) is one of the fundaments of the EU. Any political intervention in the operation of this machine under conditions of ever-growing global competition may have devastating implications for the EU!
It is stated in Section 5, that the EU Acquis will keep developing over the years prior to accession. The decisions on modifications will be taken by the present member countries, but they will concern the future members as well. The Acquis will probably evolve towards greater liberalisation of goods, capital and labour markets, important modifications of the Common agricultural policy, of structural and regional policy arrangements, etc. Ecological, labour, social, health protection and other standards will grow stricter. This is a normal process of development and adjustment of the Acquis. The challenges facing the new members by 2010 will be greater than the present ones and those which will be applied for the applicants from the first group, say by 2005.
Having all that in mind, we recommend to the governments of Bulgaria and the other CEE countries to submit a joint proposal to the European Commission for establishing a clear–cut procedure, regulating the participation of representatives of the applicant countries at an observatory status, in all working and political fora, when issues, conserning them as future members are discussed and decisions taken.
8. Preparation for the Common Agricultural Policy
The funds for the Common agricultural policy (CAP) and for the rural development were 40,92 bill. Euro – the largest component of the EU budget for 2000. Its share was 45,7% in 2000, and is expected to reach 46, 6% in 2006.
The size of the expenditures, the complexity of the programme and the ongoing discussion on its present philosophy and future orientation call for a comprehensive assessment of the current situation of the Bulgarian agriculture, the preparatory measures and the expected costs and benefits after accession.
Due to the importance of the problems and the difficulties to foresee the forthcoming changes in the CAP over the next ten years and beyond it is advisable to apply scenarios based on different assumptions concerning:
Forecasts for the positive and negative effects from the CAP are very difficult to make. This necessitates a cautious approach. The estimated effects by the different scenarios should be used both at macro- and micro level.
9. Preparation for the Structural Policy of the European Union
The structural funds absorbed 32,05 bill. Euro of the Union’s budget in 2000. From 35.8% in 2000 their share is expected to be 32, 5% by 2006.
The assessments of the effects of the structural policy should be made at macro-, sectoral and regional levels. Econometric models are recommended for estimation of the macroeconomic effects. This allows for testing of the sensitivity of the results with regard to basic assumptions. This is hardly possible at regional level, due to insufficient information even in the EU countries.
There is evidence of convergence among the EU countries on GDP per capita during the last decade. The gaps among regions within EU countries are however growing. This is most likely to happen in Bulgaria, due, among other reasons, to the inflow of FDI, which will go to regions with the most attractive conditions for economic activities. It is already happening in this country.
The government’s capacities to prevent growing regional disparities will be limited. Even more so for disparities, originating from the inflow of FDI and the private domestic investment.
We recommend to the Bulgarian government to initiate a comprehensive analysis and a forecast for the possible implications of accession on the regional development of this country. One should develop a regional strategy by 2010 along with an appropriate policy for its implementation; identify the regions, which need support the most, and introduce economic incentives to make them more attractive for Bulgarian and foreign investors.
10. Preparation for High Investment Activity
In Section 5, we argue on the imperative for large investments to comply with the Acquis and the EU standards – around $110–120 bill. over the next 25–30 years. On this basis high investment rates are projected for the pre-accession period – between 26 and 30%. During the first half of this period around 95% of the overall investment will be provided by Bulgaria, and for the second half – 90%.
In Section 5.2 is stated that accession preparation investments during the next ten years should be very high if Bulgaria (and other applicant countries) are to comply with the EU standards. This would bring the overall investment rate to at least 43-45%. Such investment activity, however, is not feasible, due to both shortage of absorbtion capacities and lack of financing.
Therefore, instead of earmarking investments for comprehensive accession preparation 23-25% of GDP for ten years, Bulgaria (and other applicant countries) will confine itselve to 8-10%. Reducing annual accession related investment by a factor of three means extending the time for preparation by the same factor. With accession related investment rate of 8-10% Bulgaria (and other candidate countries) needs 25-30 years to do the job, not 10 years. She might accede in ten years, but will not be able to comply with the EU standards.
Bulgaria should provide 92-93% of the overall investment for the next 10 yers. They should come from domestic (private and public) saving, FDI, foregn borrowing, and foreign capital markets. This, in turn necessitates appropriate economic, institutional and other prerequisites to generate much higher domestic savings by an exhausted economy and households with very low incomes. This also presupposes appropriate environment for attraction of FDI after completion of privatization and cautious borrowing, due to high external indebtedness.
The heavy indebtedness makes the FDI a preferable alternative. The development of an appropriate policy for attraction of FDI calls for thorough analysis of the past experience and present policy, and drawing lessons. Comprehensive studies have been carried on in CE countries on the economic penetration of FDI as well as comparative analyses of economic performance of foreign and local companies, using a number of economic indicators - overall, by sectors, subsectors and branches (see Section 4.3.5).
Such studies should be undertaken in Bulgaria too with financial support by the Foreign Investment Agency (FIA). The Agency should also expand and substantiate the information it publishes on FDI. The discrepancies between the FDI information, published by the Bulgarian National Bank, the Central Statistical Office and the FIA should also be clarified and sorted out. To this end lessons should be learned from the experience of the CE countries.
The Government should provide a portion of the domestic savings. The prevailing number of infrastructure projects built with foreign participation should be supported by domestic public funds as well. Other infrastructure projects are to be built predominantly with public funds. This will be an additional burden to the budget for many years. The budget must also shoulder the heavy external debt service for many years to come. This will in turn limit the maneuverability of the state in this area.
Under this complex environment the government should develop a ten-year investment strategy for financing the preparation of Bulgaria to comply with the EU standards. This strategy should trace out the approximate size of needed investment; the sources of financing (domestic saving, FDI, external borrowing, capital markets, EU transfers); the role of the public and private sectors; tentative allocation by sectors, activities and major projects; tentative time sequencing.
11. Bulgaria Needs Larger Pre-Accession Transfers from the EU
The gross transfers to all applicants from the pre-accession funds are budgeted at 3,12 bill. Euro per annum up to 2006. This amounts to 3,4% of overall EU appropriations for payments.
The Financial Perspective EU-15 and the Financial Framework EU–21 provide for gradual switching in of the new members to the Community funds for the initial five years. The access might be more or less normal only at the fifth year. This is not appropriate, as the applicants need resources for preparation mostly during the pre–accession and the years immediately after accession. The budget provisions prove that just over these years they will get thither financing.
The member countries do not get gross, but net transfers. The receipt of the net transfers is also not certain and does not equal the net gains. This will be subject to the absorption capacities of the applicants and the new members and compliance with specific requirements. At low absorption capacities there might be no net gains.
Gross transfers from the pre-accession funds of 3.4% of the EU budget, and only 1% of the annual GDP of the applicant countries are far from been enough. Even the most advanced candidate countries need more than 30% annual overall investment rates over the following years to comply with the EU standards. This is a clear manifestation of the meager financial support by the EU. Such transfers are not consistent with the political statements of top European Commission officials on the high priority they assign to enlargement.
The dangers of premature accession of ill-prepared economies are real. This must be kept in mind. It is not wise on the part of the applicants to insist blindly for a quick accession, and on the part of the EU – to make generous promising statements, without cool–minded assessment of the consequences of acceding unprepared members. Even some EU publications are concerned about that. The concern is however unnoticeable in the public appearances of the top EU officials.
The solution should be sought in full mobilization of the national energy of the applicant countries and increased EU transfers prior to and after accession.
If a decision is to be taken on substantial increase of transfers during the pre-accession period, one may also consider their composition. The bulk of the transfers (70–80 %) should be a subsidy, as it has been so far. Its share may vary, subject to the level of development of the applicants, their economic and financial position, current domestic and external indebtedness, balance of payments position and so on. For the most backward applicant countries, such as Bulgaria, this share should be as high as 90–95 %, while for the more advanced applicants – up to 50–60 %.
The balance could be long-term (25–35 year’s) soft loans with servicing vacancy (10-15 years) and lower than the market interest rate. The European Commission might be instrumental in identifying similar soft loans from other sources: the World Bank, the European Bank, the European Investment Bank and other official lenders.
Which are the arguments, supporting such a recommendation:
An increase in the EU transfers prior to and immediately after accession should be negotiated through multilateral negotiations between the EU and the CEECs. Full mobilization of national resources of the applicant countries along with larger transfers would assure better preparation for accession. The well-prepared new members are a guarantee for normal functioning of the Single Market and the expanded Union. This is in everybody’s interest – to the present and the new members of the Union.
12. More Caution is Needed in Forecasting the Economic Growth and Convergence with the European Union
The GDP per capita in Bulgaria, the long-term and very distant prospects of its increase are argued in Sections 1.2 and 2.2.1. Excessive optimism is being witnessed in this country in projections for GDP growth, and convergence with the EU on GDP per capita, productivity, competitiveness, incomes, etc. Important political decisions are been taken on this ground. The thorough investigation of the experience of other countries of comparable size and level of development proves that it is not so simple.
Bulgaria and the other countries, still in transformation recession, may reach high growth rates (5-6%) for several years due to very low basis. With the recovery of the pre-reform level of output the transitional growth potential will be depleted and the growth rate will take a normal pace.
Competent researchers of growth state explicitly that "…convergence takes time: On the assumption that the average convergence rate found in the cross-country regression holds true for the convergence of the CEECs, it will take approximately 35 years for the CEEC–10 to achieve 55 per cent, and for the first round candidates - 60 per cent of the average per capita income in the present EU. Depending on the initial income, growth rates would initially vary between 3,5 and 5,5 per cent across the CEECs. …Any realistic policy scenario has to acknowledge the fact, that the large gap in per capita incomes between the present EU and most of the CEECs will persist for decades rather than just years". And there is no guarantee that the process will be smooth.
One may forecast with a high degree of likelihood that the GDP per capita growth rate in Bulgaria will be around 4% over the next 15 – 20 years. For the next ten years the annual rate will be 4,5-5.0%, while for the first half of the decade – 5,5%. Of course, provided an appropriate domestic economic policy, favourable internal and external economic, social and political environment are in place.
It is also high time for some Bulgarian politicians to cease imposing the primitive concept of the so-called "two–digit nominal GDP growth rate" as a tool for an economic convergence with the EU. The attempts to impose such a naïve concept are professionally untenable and may discredit Bulgaria in front of the international community.
13. Accession of Bulgaria to the European Union and to the Economic and Monetary Union
Bulgaria and the other CEE countries are aiming at accession to the EU, and later on – to the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). Some Bulgarian politicians and government economists have even claimed that the country had already met the Maastricht convergence criteria and should accede to the EMU. The two goals are interrelated, but autonomous. In a more distant future (13-15 years or more) they may converge. This is however not the case in the short– and medium–term.
The analyses and the projections of both Eastern and Western European researchers indicate that the real appreciation of the currencies of the candidate countries with pegged exchange rates will go on (and may even accelerate) during the pre-accession period. This also applies to the Bulgarian currency. It is an inevitable byproduct of the convergence to the EU. This "… requires that their price levels or nominal exchange rates (or both) be able to adjust".
The convergence of GDP per capita, of productivity and incomes goes along with the convergence of the average price levels, particularly for the tradable goods. This will be, however impossible if inflation in Bulgaria were equal or close to the one in Western Europe. Therefore, somewhat higher inflation and depreciation of nominal exchange rates in the applicant countries are normal and desirable within the context of convergence.
Bulgaria and the other CEE countries cannot converge with the EU member countries by GDP per capita, productivity, competitiveness and incomes if they adhere to a policy of very low inflation and pegged exchange rates for a long time. A choice has to be made – either high growth rates of GDP, productivity and competitiveness, or very low inflation and pegged exchange rate for 10–15 years. The logical choice is more than obvious! Sustainable high growth however is not compatible with a pegged exchange rate for a long period of time.
Some Bulgarian politicians and official economists insist that the country must stick to low inflation and to the present fixed exchange rate in compliance with the Maastrich criteria and the Currency Board arrangement until accession to the EU and the EMU, namely in the next 10–15 years.
At least two points are worth reiteration: First, it is domestically inconsistent to set up two objectives: stabilization of prices and of exchange rate. Second, if Bulgaria aimed at simultaneous accession to the EU and the EMU, and even joining the EMU before the EU, as some high ranking Bulgarian politicians believe (which is unthinkable), the opportunities for convergence with the EU by GDP per capita and other important indicators will be jeopardized. Because this would require low inflation and pegged exchange rate during the whole pre-accession period and beyond. Suppressing inflation by fixed exchange rate, controlled prices, and vigorously balanced budget might be even harmful to the economy.
Such twin objectives in a package are incompatible. Even less so under increasing domestic deregulation and complete liberalization of goods and capital flows with the EU, "Stability of the exchange rate in a country with highly under–priced goods does imply inflation. One of the two goals has to be abandoned. Worse still, as practice has repeatedly shown that the attempts at meeting such incompatible goals usually end in developments resulting in both goals being abandoned". This thesis has been asserted a number of times in our publications in the recent years.
14. Monetary and Fiscal Policies during the Pre-Accession Period
As stated above, Bulgaria and the other CEE countries need large investments during the pre–accession period to comply with the EU standards. These resources will be secured mainly from domestic saving and to a lesser extent – by external flows. This will burden the budget by public investment for infrastructure and indirectly – through higher debt service payments.
Restructuring and re-capitalisation in the corporate and financial sectors may also burden the budget. Health and pension reforms will have similar implications, particularly under conditions of high unemployment, low personal incomes, low collection rate of social security contributions, aging population and increased emigration of young people. Trade liberalisation and joining the Customs Union will reduce the budget revenues from import tariffs and taxes. The adjustment of the domestic tax system to the EU standards aiming at gradual unification may reduce some taxes. On the other hand, the financing of accession preparations may generate pressure for higher taxes.
A balanced budget is indispensable and desirable for the economy, but has its price. If the "price" of the balanced budget is too high, as it is expected to be during the pre–accession period, flexibility should be exercised in the name of achieving fundamental economic, social and other goals. The balanced budget is not an end of economic policy, but simply a means.
Bulgaria needs FDI and external borrowing. Approaching accession is expected to boost investment inflows. Particularly during the second half of the new decade. This will increase money supply and boost inflation pressure.
Under these conditions closer coordination is needed between monetary and fiscal policies to neutralise the possible negative implications from capital inflows and particularly from sensitive short–term flows. Bulgaria also needs to regain its prerogatives on national monetary and foreign exchange policies at least by accession to the EMU. This calls for flexibility of the macroeconomic policies. Much higher than permitted by the Currency Board arrangement and allowed by a strict adherence to the Maastricht convergence criteria.
As far as Bulgaria is concerned, flexibility is required with regard to the Currency Board arrangement, if and when circumstances called for. A blind adherence to the view that the country will accede to the EU and EMU with a Currency Board, i.e. without monetary and foreign exchange policies may have grave consequences for the economy.
If more important national interests necessitate one must be ready for adjustments in the Currency Board arrangement. This however does not mean abandoning of all its instruments. By that we mean a more flexible exchange rate policy, for instance moving to crawling peg exchange rate system. It is very likely that more important economic and social goals will necessitate such an adjustment. This change does not look indispensable within a year or two, unless appreciation of the Euro proves faster than expected at the end of 2000; if the oil prices rise beyond limit and if the US economy fails with the soft landing.
As stated in Sections 1 and 2, the economic convergence of the CEE, and Bulgaria in particular, with the EU will take decades, rather than years. Much longer, than accession to the EU, the EMU and the adoption of the Euro.
This convergence necessitates application of flexible macro– and microeconomic policies. The successful economic and social development of Bulgaria is a fundamental goal, far more important than any instrument of economic policy, such as low inflation, balanced budget, fixed exchange rate, and so on. Apparently, the means must be subordinated to the goals and not vise versa. And short-term objectives – to long-term goals.
It follows from the above, that during the pre–accession period the design and implementation of rational policy on more balanced budget and balance of payments, pegged exchange rate, low inflation and so on will be more complicated than it has been so far. The compliance with vital criteria for accession to the EU (higher GDP growth rate, productivity, competitiveness, incomes) over the new decade will be at variance with the convergence criteria for accession to the EMU (balanced budget, low inflation, stable exchange rate, low public debt).
The overcoming of differences and the temporary conflicts between the above mentioned goals and the means for their attainment is possible, no matter how difficult it might be. It calls for a recognition of the existence of such a problem; understanding of its complexity; a display of economic imagination and flexibility in the design of monetary, foreign exchange and fiscal policies. As stated above, the macroeconomic policy should not be tuned in simultaneously to both objectives – the EU and the EMU. Such an approach will lead to a failure in achieving both goals.
Moreover, with the introduction of a Currency Board arrangement in the middle of 1997, Bulgaria has no longer its own monetary and foreign exchange policies. The Bulgarian National Bank is no longer a normal central bank. Its functions are strictly curtailed. The instruments of macroeconomic policy for management of the national economy are also more limited.
With the introduction of the Currency Board arrangement Bulgaria dispensed itself with monetary and foreign exchange policies and laid on their functions to fiscal policy. However, due to its very nature the fiscal policy cannot be an adequate substitute. The reasons are many. One of them are the long time lags, much longer than those of the monetary policy. The feedbacks in the behaviour of economic agents on the signals of fiscal policy are slow. Macroeconomic management by fiscal policy instruments is more difficult, than by monetary policy instruments.
The Ministry of Finance makes things worse by misusing the basic interest rate. This rate has been transformed into a mere administrative instrument, applied by an institution with vested interests. It serves only the balancing of budget, to the detriment of households, the economic agents and the economy as a whole.
The Government and the Board of the Bulgarian National Bank got used to this comfort and do not seem to be willing to regain sovereign monetary and foreign exchange policies. Abandoning the Currency Board arrangement will be more difficult than adopting it. This is due to indecisiveness of the Government and the Board of the National Bank, owing to their apprehension of reemergence of hyperinflation. They apparently do not understand that there are no prerequisites for this in Bulgaria now, and in the foreseeable future.
The proper understanding and the pragmatic resolution of these problems should begin now. The charms must be substituted by a cool–minded analysis and far–sighted decisions. Otherwise, if one keeps insisting that accession to the EU and the EMU is possible with operating Currency Board arrangement (with low inflation at the present pegged exchange rate), Bulgaria will face grave problems during the new decade.
15. One Should be Ready to Face the Pre–Accession Uncertainties.
The economic convergence and accession to the EU will hardly be so smooth and certain, as some people hope for! Fluctuations in the global and European economies cannot be precluded. Destabilising impulses may come from the energy prices on the global market during the coming years. There are arguments nurturing an expectation for higher oil prices. One of them is the oil price dynamics in real terms. As stated in Section 4.2.3 the oil prices in 2000 were at the level of 1973-1975 in 1990 US dollars. According to other studies the oil prices in 2000 were at the 1900 level in real terms. Too low oil prices are confortable in the short–term, but do not provide a good service to the global economy and the search for new energy sources in the long–term.
There are no guarantees that the preparation of Bulgaria will be smooth and accession will take place by 2010. The opposite is true – with present investment levels the country will not be able to comply with the most important EU standards. There are no guarantees that the internal institutional reforms of the EU will match the requirements for enlargement and globalisation. The European conference in Nice (December 2000) was a warning signal.
This may lead to delays in accession, the symptoms of which are evident for the first group countries. Accession of some of these countries, say by 2005, may not be problem free, which is quite natural for such a gigantic project. This may lead to a revision of the EU strategy and tactics on the Eastern Enlargement, delaying further the accession of Bulgaria and other countries. It is not precluded that some new members (including Bulgaria) may be placed in an intermediate transitional group of restricted membership: limited labour mobility, restricted access to the funds and programmes of the Community, a number of restrictive (for them) transitional arrangements, and so on. They may even make a third group, if the concept of the EU development on two or more speeds gets an upper hand.
The possible alternatives listed above are sources for accession risks. The risks that Bulgaria would face are greater in number and much more likely to occur than for the CE economies. The emergence of such uncertainties may have negative implications. It may decelerate the pace of reforms and the preparations for accession. It may also weaken the public support for enlargement, both in the EU and the CEE. This would make the fragile CEE economies even more vulnerable to political, economic and other shocks. It, in turn, may undermine the confidence of the world financial community and particularly of potential investors, at a time, when we are in great need of them.
Such a pessimistic scenario is possible, but not unavoidable. Its prevention depends mostly on the policies of the USA, the EU and Japan
The reconsideration of the EU policy on pre–accession transfers to the candidate countries is one of the instruments of preventing such unfavourable developments in Europe. The well–prepared future members would be an important stabilising factor for the expanded Union. And vise versa – the ill–prepared new members will be a source of instability.
The EU member countries should look for an appropriate mix among three variables of the Eastern enlargement (accession deadlines, transfers and transitional arrangements) in order to accede only the well–prepared new members:
One should not close one’s eyes. With present transfers from pre-accession funds; with present tentative accession deadlines; and present policy to keep transitional arrangements to a minimum, the new members from CEE will not be prepared properly for accession. They will not be able to assume their responsibilities and perform as full-fledged members immediately, or soon after accession.
The leaders of the EU, of the member countries and of the candidate countries should take this warning seriously before it is too late!
![]() |