Institute of Economics of the Bulgarian Academy of Sciences

 

Friedrich Ebert Foundation

 

 

Strategy for Accelerated Economic Development of Bulgaria by 2020

 

Summary of Conclusions

and Recommendations

 

 

Sofia, January 2004

 

 

 

Authors

 

Prof. Dr. Ivan Angelov – Team leader

 

Dr. Tatiana Hubenova-Delisivkova

Dr. Ivanka Kraininska

Dr. Malinka Koparanova

Dr. Matiu Matev

Dr. Goran Bankov

Stefan Uzunov

 

 

Translated from Bulgarian into English by Mariana Hill.

English text edited by Prof. Ivan Angelov

 

 

All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any electronic or mechanical means without permission in writing by the authors.

 

 

Back to the List of Publicatirons

 

Table of Contents

 

Part one. Accelerated Development – Substance, Necessity, Sources and Objectives

 

1.1. Conclusions of global and regional importance

1.1.1. Global economic divergence

1.1.2. Increase of social polarisation

1.1.3. Economic miracles” can’t be reproduced

1.1.4. Development as a transformation of society

1.1.5. Integration and economic convergence

1.1.6. Controversial trends in CEECs

1.1.7. Controversial trends in regional convergence

1.1.8. Drivers of economic growth

 

1.2. Conclusions and recommendations of national (Bulgarian) importance

1.2.1. Compounding of fundamental processes

1.2.2. Wrong reform philosophy

1.2.3. Functioning and competitive market economy

1.2.4. Two development routes

1.2.5. Functions, components and resources of the strategy

1.2.6. Fundamental priorities

1.2.7. The human being – the major benefactor of the strategy

1.2.8. A system of development indicators

1.2.9. Objectives and means of economic development

1.2.10. Economic growth scenarios

1.2.11. Economic target indicators

1.2.12. Social target indicators

1.2.13. Environmental target indicators

1.2.14. The quality of statistical information

1.2.15. Labour participation and employment

1.2.16. Labour productivity

1.2.17. Total factor productivity

1.2.18. Menu of growth factors

 

Part Two. Recommendations for Economic Policy Priorities for Achievement of Strategic Objectives

 

2.1. The role of government

 

2.2. Strategic priorities of economic policy

 

2.3. Transmission mechanisms from economic policies to economic growth

2.3.1. Macroeconomic stability

2.3.2. Regulation and deregulation

2.3.3.   Competition and types of property

2.3.4.   Foreign economic policy

2.3.5.   Policy for savings and investment in physical capital

 2.3.6. Human capital development policy

 2.3.7. Employment enhancement policy

2.3.8. Income policy

2.3.9. Mitigating the consequences of the demographic crisis

2.3.10. Alleviating social polarisation and alienation

2.3.11. Economic aspects of innovation policy

2.3.12. Economic dimensions of break-through science and technology developments

2.3.13. Consumer patterns and consumption policy

2.3.14. Policy on Innovation of production patterns

2.3.15. Financial system development and resource mobilisation

2.3.16. Institutional policy

2.3.17. Economic aspects of environmental policy

 

Annex. Table of contents of the full text published in Bulgarian

 

 

In this extended summary – about 10% of the full text of the study, we present the most important conclusions and recommendations.

There are hundreds of conclusions and recommendations in the full text of the study. It is impossible, however, to include all of them in the summary. For obvious reasons no room is devoted to argumentation here. It is in the main text.

No tables are given here on the international experience in economic convergence or Bulgaria’s economic, social and environmental development until 2010 and 2020 and in some cases until 2050. For these 29 tables too one must refer to the full text. For the readers’ ease, we refer here to the respective tables in the main text.

The bibliography is also not included in the summary. It comprises references to more than 400 publications in Bulgarian and other languages. Refer to the full text for these too.

 

 

Part One. Accelerated Development – Substance, Necessity, Sources and Objectives

 

The analysis provides a foundation for the following most important conclusions and recommendations:

 

 

1.1. Conclusions of Global and Regional Importance

 

1.1.1. Global Economic Divergence

 

There is no unquestionable trend of sustainable global economic convergence. It is not evident even between the three main development centres – the US, Japan and the EU (see tables 2.2 and 2.3)[1]. The diverging level of developed and underdeveloped countries creates the potential for the latter to develop more quickly and reduce the divergence with the more advanced ones. This opportunity can only be realised under a combination of appropriate economic and other conditions. Creating such prerequisites is difficult and is rarely achieved. Some western authors’ claims that the average speed of convergence is two percentage points per annum are occasionally valid for some developed countries. Convergence is often slower or absent, particularly between developed and less developed economies.

Empirical proof does not confirm the hypothesis of global economic convergence implied in the neo-classical models. There is no clear-cut trend for more rapid development of the underdeveloped countries compared to the more developed ones. The trend is a growing divergence in the levels of productivity and GDP per capita (see table 2.1.) Even when the relative differences decrease, the absolute ones grow larger. The only important exception are some countries in East and Southeast Asia (see table 2.5).

 

1.1.2. Increase of Social Polarisation

 

Accelerated economic growth goes along with an even more rapid increase of social polarisation. In 1960, per capita GDP in the 20 richest countries according to purchasing parity standards was 18 times higher than in the 20 poorest countries. By 2000 this spread was 40 times.

Rapid economic growth in itself is insufficient. It has to be for the benefit of as many people as possible on a global, regional, national and domestic regional scale. An increase of GDP can not be successful and sustainable if it is only for the benefit of a small minority. History has confirmed this on many occasions. This is relevant today too because regardless of the fact that history is never repeated in full, its main aspects often are.

 
1.1.3. “Economic Miracles” can’t be reproduced

 

Neither economic theory nor economic practices have discovered easy solutions and practical recipes for rapid economic convergence. Global experience proves that “economic miracles” are a result of a unique combination of country specific favourable conditions, aggressive economic, institutional, social and other policies, appropriate geographical location and a coincidence of circumstances in a specific historical context.

Progress in economic convergence is unique for any country. It is impossible to replicate it in other countries and times. “Economic miracles” can be explained post factum but they can not be reproduced. New “economic miracles” can benefit from the lessons of the preceding ones but they will always contain unique innovative national elements. Otherwise they would never happen! Each country that wants an “economic miracle” has to “make it happen”.

 

1.1.4. Development as a Transformation of Society

 

According to the modern paradigms development does not boil down to technical change – accumulation of physical and human capital, financial stability, higher labour productivity, competitiveness etc. As stated by J. Stiglitz, development means a transformation of society. The contemporary understanding of development does not assume development in general, but rather intensive, democratic, fair and sustainable development. Social innovation, however, should not destroy the inherited, centuries-old traditional cultural and other national values.

It is important to produce. Productive activities however must be carried out by healthy, highly skilled, free people who live in dignity and are capable of managing their own fate in an environment of personal security. People who know that in extremely unfavourable situations they can rely on the help of the community, of the society represented by the state. These people must live in an environment of openness, transparency, partnership and personal commitment to shared ideals and take part in decision making on personal and public affairs.

Development as transformation requires something more than appropriate economic policy and efficient institutions. The new theories of development as a transformation of society along with the institutions stress the importance of distribution. The problems of normal stratification or social polarisation are very important not only as development goals, but also as means for a more efficient performance of the economy. Poor people suffer not only because of a lack of means for their basic needs. They are powerless, helpless and insecure about themselves and their families. They are unwanted and rejected by society. Given such a social environment it is impossible to ensure a normal development of society, let alone any accelerated development!

 

1.1.5. Integration and Economic Convergence

 

Theory is undecided as to whether integration always leads to economic convergence. Тhis is apparent when the strictest assumptions of the neo-classical model are made more flexible, particularly the assumption that production technologies are identical and accessible to all countries. The poorly timed removal of capital and labour market barriers between developed and less developed countries can turn into a source of growing divergence. In some versions of the endogenous growth and integration models it can induce divergence between countries in terms of GDP per capita despite the fact that in principle it has a positive overall effect.

            The experience of the less developed EU cohesion countries (Ireland, Spain, Portugal and Greece) proves that joining the European community did not result in automatic convergence. It is a possibility that can be used (Spain, Ireland and to a certain extent Portugal) or may not be used as in Greece (see table 2.6.). Its realisation presupposes the availability of a set of prerequisites – pro-active economic and other national policies of the member states is one of them. Even then convergence takes not years but decades.

            Bulgarian accession to the EU will take place under more difficult conditions. First, Bulgaria is the least prepared of the applicant countries, which have joined the EU so far. Second, Bulgaria committed to a very high pre-accession price by closing four nuclear power reactors with a total capacity of 1760 megawatts. The losses and forgone benefits of this amount to several billions of US dollars. Third, Bulgaria will receive less EU transfers per capita than the cohesion countries did after their accession. Fourth, following accession Bulgaria will have to face strong competitive pressure on the single internal market, which did not exist when Ireland, Greece, Spain and Portugal joined. Fifth, Bulgaria will accede at a time when the EU will be struggling with the inevitable problems of the Eastern enlargement in 2004 in addition to the difficulties of its own internal reforms. Any decision of a group of member countries to move faster leading to a two-speed development of the EU would affect Bulgaria negatively. Sixth, Bulgarian society is not psychologically prepared for accession. Politicians are cultivating pre-accession illusions in the public, which will inevitably transform into post-accession disillusionment.

 

1.1.6. Controversial Trends in CEECs

 

The trends in the CEECs have been controversial – both in the 40 years of centralised planning and in the 15 years of transformation. There is no trend of steady convergence (see tables 2.7 and 2.8). The trend is towards lagging behind the most developed countries, stagnation and internal divergence between the CEECs. Only some Central European Countries (CECs) are slowly converging with the developed economies of the EU-15. Bulgaria is lagging behind both the EU and the CE countries.

 

1.1.7. Controversial Trends in Regional Convergence

 

Тhe trends in regional convergence are also controversial – in terms of both the average EU level and average EU member country levels. There is slow regional convergence in the most developed countries but regional divergence continues in the less developed EU economies.

There is great regional divergence in the CEECs, which has even been growing over the past 10-15 years. Macroeconomic convergence of the less developed countries with the average EU level continues along with an increase in the national regional divergence. The higher the GDP growth in a country, the higher its internal regional divergence. This has been the case over recent decades. It will persist in the coming decades.

 

1.1.8. Drivers of Economic Growth

 

The most important driving forces of growth and economic convergence over the past decades have been investments in human and physical capital and recently in ICT (information and communications technologies), research and innovation, internal and external liberalisation, sectoral, intrasectoral and product adjustment. Financial system development, competition and entrepreneurship, financial stability, active macroeconomic policy and institutional modernisation have also been very important. Geographic proximity to the large developed countries and the powerful internal development centres also plays an important role.

The driving forces form a certain level of growth and economic convergence (divergence) by means of labour productivity, quantity of labour and total factor productivity. All three factors are important, albeit on a different level in different countries and periods of time (see table 2.9).

Table of Contents

 

 

1.2. Conclusions and Recommendations of National (Bulgarian) Importance

 

1.2.1. Compounding of Fundamental Processes

 

The compounding of several major processes and simultaneous resolution of several fundamental objectives in Bulgaria and in the countries of Southeastern Europe slowed down reforms. They impeded the resolution of all objectives – overcoming backwardness, carrying out market reforms and preparing for EU integration.

This all occurred against the harsh background of globalisation and great losses and opportunity costs to Bulgaria resulting from the UN embargoes against Iraq and former Yugoslavia. In spite of the absence of ethnic or military conflicts in Bulgaria their presence in neighbouring countries shed insecurity over Bulgaria and created additional difficulties to transition and integration.

 

1.2.2. Wrong Reform Philosophy

 

The International Financial Institutions applied wrong reform philosophy and standard schemes inappropriate to Bulgarian conditions. They persued only the means of economic policy, such as low inflation, low fiscal deficits, stable exchange rate, etc. rather than fundamental objectives such as growth, employment, income, consumption, social justice, healthy environment, etc. The health, the education, the social justice and even the life of the people were sacrificed to the altar of financial stabilisation.

External and domestic reform designers imposed a forceful speedy privatisation at any price and tolerated crony privatisation. As a result very important portion of the newly created private sector is not a bearer of positive dynamism, entrepreneurship, innovation, respect of low and order. Such a private sector does not respect loyal competition and fundamental national interests. This makes Bulgarian private sector too different from the one existent in the advanced market economies. Such private sector is not likely to contribute much to sustainable development.

The designers of reforms ignored the fact that there was no clear process of market transformation in Bulgaria. The latter had to be paired with overcoming economic, social, institutional and other backwardness.

In this complex setting the share of problems related to backwardness was smaller in Bulgaria compared to African and Asian countries and Albania but greater compared to the reforms in the Czech Republic, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia and Hungary. This was ignored when designing the reform models.

This made Bulgarian transformation more difficult and increased tremendously its social costs. Very large portion of the Bulgarian population lives now in great poverty, much larger than under central planning. The crime is flourishing. This is not what the people expected from transition.

 

1.2.3. Functioning and Competitive Market Economy

 

It is far too early to claim that there is a normally functioning market economy in Bulgaria! There are no real estate and capital markets, and the money, commodity and labour markets are in the initial phases of their development, which is accompanied by severe deformations and criminal deviations. Due to the low quality of reforms and crony privatisation Bulgaria has turned into an economic minefield. The mines explode any time when the interests of the respective economic groups are at stake. This will go on during the coming years and decades.

Bulgaria will not be able to develop a normally functioning and competitive market economy in the short and medium term. Competitiveness may become a reality only in the distant future – in 15-20 years. Normal relations between the economic agents are often replaced by criminal tools for “settling bills” - intimidation, blackmail, arson and assassinations. This creates a social, economic and psychological environment that will be counterproductive to normal economic activity for many years to come.

 The choice is clear – initiate accelerated development on a playing field that has been cleared of crime and corruption or sustain economic and social stagnation in an environment of crime and corruption. Bulgarian authorities do not seem to understand that country is at a crossroad.

 

1.2.4. Two Development Routes

 

Bulgaria can chose between two extreme routes of economic development until 2020 and by 2050:

- Lagging behind development of about 2% annual average GDP growth, or slow development of about 3%. Given PP standards, as well as expected average annual EU-15 GDP growth of 2.0-2.5% the first scenario would result in 30-35% of the per capita GDP of EU-15 by the middle of the century, or 40-45% according to the second scenario. Bulgaria will be doomed to socio-economic stagnation with grave strategic consequences.

- Accelerated or rapid accelerated development of 5.0-7.0% average annual GDP growth. It is desirable to have average annual growth of 6-8% in the first ten years, 5-6% in the next decade, 4-5% in the subsequent decade and 3-3.5% beyond that. This development will not be smooth. From the point of view of economic convergence it is crucial to have Bulgarian average annual growth exceeding EU-15 growth 2.5-3.0 times. In this case Bulgaria will achieve a per capita GDP of 50-55% of the EU-15 level by 2020 and 75-80% by 2050. Such a favourable prospect is on the bortherline between the possible and the impossible. It requires full mobilisation of national energy as well as favourable external conditions. World economic history proves that such a lucky combination is rare.

 

1.2.5. Functions, Components and Resources of the Strategy

 

The strategy for development of society has several major functions. They are: to define priorities; to co-ordinate; to contribute to attaining national consensus; to serve as a catalyst for overall social change; to be a carrier of transformation ideas, prompted by internal needs; to cultivate ownership; to provide co-operation between the state and the market.

The strategy must cover all components of society: development of the private and the public sector, of the regional communities, of the family, of the individual. The strategy should treat them as integral parts of society. It is impossible to achieve sustainable development unless it encompasses each of these components!

The strategy is a sound proposal only if backed with resources. Тhey include physical, human and financial resources, efficient macro- and microeconomic management, increase of knowledge, sectoral, subsectoral, regional and other strategies as well as social and organisational capital.

 

1.2.6. Fundamental Priorities

  

The main task of the proposed strategy on priorities is to identify the areas of sustainable development and the economic, social and other policies to be activated by the state and society.

The proposed strategy identifies the following fundamental priority areas of sustainable development:

-          improving healthcare and providing general access to health services;

-          upgrading the quality, widening the scope and improving access to education;

-          acquiring more state of the art knowledge leading to establishing a “knowledge based society”;

-          promoting research and development;

-          structural and technological upgrading of the economy;

-          developing a modern infrastructure;

-          balanced development of the regions;

-          promoting income stratification but restricting social polarisation;

-          mitigating the negative consequences of the demographic crisis;

-          protection and improvement of the environment;

-          creating modern public institutions and NGOs and an efficient administration.

These general priorities are subject to specification by means of strategies and programmes at sectoral, subsectoral, regional and company level to make them operational.

Part two of this summary offers the priority economic and social policies for achieving the strategic development priorities.

 

1.2.7. The Human Being – the Major Benefactor of the Strategy

 

Setting objectives is central to any development strategy. The main objective of this strategy is the human being. Improving the quality of life is the major reason to devise a strategy and implement economic policies.

Upgrading the quality of life is the main criterion as to whether a strategy or an economic policy is sound. In the absence of improvement after an appropriate time lag the reasons should be sought in the design of the strategy and economic policy. Policy, which does not lead to better quality of life is not an appropriate one.

In a traditional strategy the only development objective is GDP growth. GDP, however, does not reflect sufficiently the quality of life of the people. It is a very important prerequisite for wellbeing but is not a reliable measure of it. Such a measure is the sustainable development indicator that covers economic, social and environmental dimensions. The economic, social and environmental objectives interact and enhance each other. This results in powerful synergies.

 

1.2.8. A System of Development Indicators

 

Notwithstanding its shortcomings, GDP is a very important aggregate indicator for economic development. There is no better indicator for operational purposes. The attempts to construct an aggregate indicator for sustainable development have not been completed so far.

 In order to compensate for the shortcomings of the GDP, we use a pyramid system of target indicators. GDP tops the pyramid. There are the four important aggregate objectives – economic development, social development, healthy environment and stable democracy in the middle layer. There are a large number of more concrete objectives that specify each of the four groups of aggregate objectives in the base of the pyramid. The political objectives are not covered in this strategy while the social and environmental ones are covered only partially.

 

1.2.9. Objectives and Means of Economic Development

 

The main objective of the accelerated sustainable development is to improve the quality of people’s lives measured with GDP and the system of economic, social and environmental indicators.

The means for attaining strategic objectives are the monetary, fiscal and foreign economic policies, employment and income policies, structural, investment, science and technology, educational and health policies, demographic policy, infrastructure upgrading policy, etc.

In more specific terms, a low inflation, balanced budget, balanced trade and current accounts, stable exchange rates, foreign exchange reserve, moderate indebtedness and others are important means of economic policies, not their objectives.

Maintaining low budget deficit or surplus by reducing investment in infrastructure and expenditures for healthcare, education and research has a negative impact on growth in the medium and long term. This generates negative consequences for employment, income, consumption, healthcare, education, research and ultimately - for the quality of life! This may balance the budget in the short run but at a too high cost – an unhealthy and uneducated generation growing up in Bulgaria, as it is now the case! The health and education of the population have much higher value in ranking public objectives than a temporarily balanced budget!

In all CEE countries where the IMF has had stand-by agreements over the last decade the objectives of economic policies were confused with their means. Bulgarian governments shared the same philosophy of transformation. Confusing the ends with the means of economic policy leads to self-deception, slows transformation, makes it more expensive and has grave consequences for the life of the population

 

1.2.10. Economic Growth Scenarios

 

We assume under the above-mentioned conditionalities that the per capita GDP is a very important aggregate indicator for economic development and, to some extent, for the quality of people’s life. The standard of life depends to a great extent (but not fully) on the dynamics of growth of per capita GDP.

Six scenarios have been constructed for the average annual per capita GDP growth by 2020, and for the sake of reflection – until 2050. These are at GDP growth of 3%, 4%, 4.5%, 5.0%, 5.5% as well as a flexible realistic scenario (5.5%) until 2020, gradually falling to 3% over the period 2041-2050 (see table 4.1 and chart 4.1.).


We recommend the scenarios of 5.0-5.5% average annual growth by 2020 to the authorities. Given the same starting point of 2000 with an average annual growth of 5.0% (and for the EU-15 of 2.0% until 2010 and 2.5% for 2011-2020), in 2020 Bulgaria can reach approximately 50% of the expected per capita GDP level of EU-15. In the case of 5.5% average annual growth Bulgaria could reach about 55% of the expected level of this index for the EU-15. This is an immensely difficult task. It verges on the impossible but could be achieved with a full mobilisation of national energy and favourable external conditions.

The recent economic history of Bulgaria (1950-1990) shows that an average annual growth of 5.0-5.5% over a 20 year period is not inconceivable (see table 2.7) evaluated in the light of the present criteria impacted by the deep crisis of transition. These comparisons, however, must be made carefully. There are differences in circumstances between the two periods that can impede the achievement of steady growth now. There are also differences in circumstances that can make it easier. It is difficult to say which of the two will prevail.

 

1.2.11. Economic Target Indicators

 

Setting the objectives based only on GDP growth implies a great risk of strategic mistakes. In order to compensate for the imperfection of GDP we recommend a system of eight economic and related target indicators and set their tentative numerical levels or trends until 2010 and 2020. (see tables 4.2.-4.9). They are: productivity and competitiveness, employment, income and consumption, education and training, digital literacy, mitigation of the demographic crisis, balanced regional development and local self-government, free migration and labour mobility.

We recommend several additional analytical target indicators for each of them and make quantitative and qualitative estimates for their levels and/or trends for the 2010 and 2020 horizon. Altogether 30 economic target indicators are used.

 

1.2.12. Social Target Indicators

 

To compensate for the imperfection of GDP we recommend a system of eight social and related target indicators with estimations until 2010 and 2020 (see tables 4.10-4.11). They are: fair distribution, social cohesion, access to health service, social protection for the needy, protection of consumer rights, social inclusion, a healthy working environment, high quality of labour and flexible professional careers, awareness and preparedness for transformations in the family and for the life style changes.

For each of those that can be quantified we recommend several analytical target indicators and estimate their level and/or trends until 2010 and 2020. For the rest we offer a description of the expected trends. Altogether 25 social and related target indicators are used.

Today only a society that provides prerequisites for its members to income based on merit is successful. The industrious and knowledgeable generate more wealth and should acquire more than the incompetent and passive. Each infringement of this fundamental principle suppresses the incentives for work, knowledge, skill and entrepreneurship. Without these qualities society is doomed to stagnation and a fatal end. The normal social and economic development presumes moderate-income stratification, but no income polarisation. Social polarisation makes accelerated economic development impossible whereas moderate social stratification boosts it.

 

1.2.13. Environmental Target Indicators

 

Bearing in mind that the protection of the environment is the third major pillar of sustainable development we share some ideas and recommend target indicators (see table 4.12.). We define environmental efficiency and its importance and investigate the link between GDP growth on one side and use of raw materials, energy, water, transport services and harmful emissions – on the other.

We propose five groups of measures for de-coupling environmental pressures from economic growth. This will help easing environmental pressure while accelerating growth. Environmental resources are and in the forthcoming decades will become even scarcer production factor than the traditional resources – labour, capital and land.

This is even more indispensable considering that environmental degradation has reached a scale that endangers the future of mankind. The seemingly weaker pressure on the environment over recent years is mainly due to reduced economic activity, rather than owing to efficient environmental policy. Environmental pressures will grow again to dangerous levels in the coming years and decades with the expected revival of economic activity despite more up to date production patterns and technologies.

Bulgaria needs a long-term strategy for the protection of environment as an integral component of sustainable development.

 

1.2.14. The Quality of Statistical Information

 

There are many question marks on important economic indicators and on the quality of statistical information in Bulgaria. Is GDP growing indeed and if so, by how much? What is the labour intensity of production measured by the average number of employed persons per annum, man-days and man-hours? What is the volume and what are the structural characteristics of the operating fixed capital and its annual depreciation? Bulgarian statistics have not published such data for 15 years and the available data is not reliable. This makes it inapplicable for analytical and management purposes.

It is impossible to calculate reliable labour productivity. There is no data on man-days and man-hours, and the published data on the number of employees is not reliable. This makes impossible drawing conclusions about economic policy. It is impossible to calculate capital productivity or important indicators such as capital/output or incremental capital/output ratios based on which one can draw conclusions about economic policy. It is equally impossible to calculate total factor productivity in this country.

 Factorial growth analysis based on a production function of the Cob-Douglas type or on the R. Sollow model is also impossible. Analyses of growth by means of more complex econometric models are even less reliable. Results of such analyses can not be used for operational business management at a macro and micro level. Even less so for medium and long-term strategic management.

 

1.2.15. Labour Participation and Employment

 

Labour activity and participation are changing slowly. Population decline will go on in the coming decades. The population in the active age will also decrease. Even in the case of stabilisation of labour participation the possibilities for GDP growth will be restricted under constant working time utilisation and labour productivity. In the case of a moderate decrease of labour participation, the impact on potential economic growth will be even more negative. It will be compounded by the worsening age composition of the labour force.

Bulgaria can, however, increase significantly the number of the employed until 2020 and beyond by increasing the participation and the employment rates (see table 5.1.) This increase will be most significant in the first decade and in the first half of the second decade. It will decline towards the end of the second decade by reducing unemployment to normal levels. By the beginning of the third decade this potential will be exhausted and so will its favourable impact on economic growth. The negative impact of decreasing employment beyond that can only be compensated with better utilisation of working time and higher productivity. This can also be aided by immigration of work force.

By 2020 and in the decades thereafter, Bulgaria will have great potential to increase the total number of worked man-hours. This growth potential will exist even under unchanged labour productivity. Considering that the latter will also grow Bulgaria will have significant economic growth potential in terms of available working time in days and hours per employed person although total number of employment will decline in subsequent decades. Using this potential will depend on the economic policy. The labour force will not be an obstacle for accelerated development in the coming decades despite the decrease in it’s size.

 

1.2.16. Labour Productivity

 

By 2020 and beyond Bulgaria will rely on a manifold increase of labour productivity as a major factor of socio-economic progress. Whereas total working time will grow in percentage terms, the increase of labour productivity will be manifold. If until 2020 per capita GDP grows by 5.5% per annum on average and if 60% of this growth is due to higher labour productivity, it would have to grow by 3.3% on average, and towards the end of the period – by 1.9 times (see table 5.2.). If productivity accounts for 70% of GDP growth on average for the entire period, until 2050 it can grow approximately 6 times compared to 2000.

Taking into account the demographic and migration prospects the major sources for extensive growth by means of the labour force will be “depleted” by 2025-2030. If the current demographic trends remain unchanged, the main and even single source for accelerated development in the coming decades will be the growing labour productivity. It will maintain its decisive role even in the case of a significant turn of the migration flows after 2020-2025. The return of some of the highly skilled emigrants may even speed up this process.

Various scenarios for substitution between labour and physical capital are possible. In the countries where labour costs are high there is a tendency to replace labour with capital by rapid increases of the capital/labour ratio. There are no economic prerequisites in Bulgaria for fast substitution during the first and probably during the second decade due to the low cost of labour. With time labour cost will grow in parallel with labour quality and productivity, but they will hardly reach levels which will speed up labour’s substitution with physical capital by 2020. This process will become more apparent during the third decade and beyond. This will provide the technical and economic foundations for an even faster increase of labour productivity.

 

1.2.17. Total Factor Productivity

 

Total factor productivity will play a growing role for maintaining accelerated growth in the first and even more so in the second decade and beyond. In the 5.5% annual GDP growth scenario until 2020, 30-40% thereof will be attributable to total factor productivity. This share will be 15-20% in the first decade, and 40-50% in the second (see tables 5.3 and 5.4). In the decades thereafter the share of total factor productivity can stabilise around 55-65%. The expected technological and other innovations and further deterioration of the demographic crisis can make a higher share of total factor productivity in GDP growth in certain periods possible or even indispensable.

Some believe that intensive growth will follow immediately under a high-tech oriented development, such as ICT, biotechnology etc., paired with non-technological elements.

This is a complicated process. A long period of economic maturing is necessary until the results of a modern economic development become effective. The so-called Paradox of Sollow is a good illustration.

This paradox, however, prompts an important conclusion for Bulgarian economic policy. Rapid changes are essential if 30-40 and more years are needed for tangible results to emerge after technological and other innovations were implemented. If this applies to the most developed countries, it is even more essential for a small and not well-organised economy like that of Bulgaria.

In order to gain time the technological, structural, institutional and other innovations in Bulgaria must start sooner and on a larger scale. The sooner the changes the sooner the results will become evident (after the essential lag). Unlike developed countries, Bulgaria can not reduce the time for economic maturing. It can, however, prolong it by delayed action. It does not seem that Bulgarian policy makers are aware of this.

Under current conditions Bulgaria will hardly have to wait for 30-40 years before the results of the technological innovations appear in the economic statistics. If we want these to transpire sooner, albeit marginally in the second and third decade, and to have them feed through to accelerated development we must act now – in 2004-2007 - and on a larger scale in the following years.

 

1.2.18. Menu of Growth Factors

 

When devising the operating strategy for accelerated economic development for Bulgaria the selected menu of growth factors is of paramount importance with reference to the share of labour, capital and total factor productivity. Full employment can be one extreme. This would secure a significant share for labour and a modest share for capital under a moderate increase of labour productivity and of total factor productivity. The other extreme can be a maximum increase of total factor productivity and of labour productivity by moderately growing employment and maintaining significant unemployment (see table 5.4).

The most reasonable option is somewhere between the two extremes. The restricted investment capacity, the moderate import potential and the use of high-tech with modest skills, discipline and other qualities of the labour force will contribute to this result. One must also take into account the social dimension – providing employment for everyone who is willing and able to work.

Table of Contents

 

 

Part Two. Recommendations for Economic Policy Priorities for Achievement of Strategic Objectives

 

The analysis provides the foundation for the following most important conclusions and recommendations:

 

 

2.1. The Role of Government

 

Government’s main role is to provide an appropriate economic, institutional, social and political environment for business activities. The government must not be a business entity except in rare cases. It creates a healthy business climate by means of economic, institutional and other policies. It drafts the laws and sees to their unconditional enforcement. International experience has proven that no one performs these functions better than the government.

The government performs its functions in co-operation with the market and not in opposition to it. Their relations are complementary rather than substitutable. One must apply the constructive principle of “both the government and the market” instead of the naïve destructive schemes of “the government or the market”. This primitive construct has not functioned anywhere.

The government must provide equal conditions for the performance of both the private and public sector. They must operate in a competitive market environment and should be equal before the law. The major prerequisite for prosperity of companies is competitiveness rather than the type of ownership.

Table of Contents

 

2.2. Strategic Priorities of Economic Policy

 

The traditional concept of “priority areas” in the strategies for economic development from the times of central planning was to directly or indirectly outline what, how, where and how much was to be produced and to whom and at what price it was to be delivered. The sectors, sub-sectors and products to be developed were specified in advance – in terms of volume, investment projects, technologies, employment etc. The time of such strategies has passed along with the rejection of central planning and the transition towards a market economy.

We do not share this concept of priorities. Neither do we agree with the current government intuitive choice of selected priority areas such as new technologies, tourism, agriculture and infrastructure. These priorities are too general to be meaningful.

Priority areas of public policy include сreating appropriate economic, institutional, social and other conditions for entrepreneurship, scientific and technological research and development under clearly defined rules. These rules comprise fair competition, health standards, social justice, environmental considerations, personal and property civil security, equality before the law, national security and other major national values.

Scientists can detect trends, offer target scenarios and policies for their achievement. Government institutions along with the social partners and NGOs discuss and adopt them. The government sets outlines of strategic goals, major policies and rules and the institutions that will enforce them.

The further formulation and implementation of development strategy with its priorities depends on the market and on the changes in the internal and external environment. Within this general framework market agents decide what, how much, how, where and when to produce, as well as to whom and how to sell, how to organise the production process and the relations between the business, social and other partners.

Specific strategies and priorities at sub-sector, company and product level should be devised by the businesses, while government must help in implementation by creating appropriate economic and institutional environment.

The government should monitor and interfere only with respect to compliance with the law. Effectiveness should be the concern of the business entities, which act on their own account and responsibility. They bear the full risk both for their action or inaction.

The government can also initiate the formulation of specific priorities in the areas of science, research and development, healthcare, education, demographic issues, environment protection, infrastructure development, regional development and others. It should discuss ideas with the businesses and other social partners, with academia, regional communities and NGOs. Decisions should be made with respect to level of specification and implementation (at government, sub-sectoral, regional, company levels); mid-term and final goals; financial, personnel, institutional and other support; subsidies etc.

The government must back its priority initiatives by providing appropriate economic and other environment for their implementation and in some cases even funding. Each level makes decisions on priorities independently by taking the overall government strategic framework into account. The respective parties should be free to deviate from government priorities at their own initiative and responsibility.

Table of Contents

 

2.3. Transmission Mechanisms from Economic Policies to Economic Growth

 

One can assume that financial stability, technological and other innovations, work force skills and other factors have a positive impact on economic growth. This is beneficial, but insufficient. These causalities must be proven empirically as well. No such in-depth research has been conducted in Bulgaria so far largely due to unreliable and insufficient information.

The study comprises an attempt to model economic growth in Bulgaria and prove the existence of such causality. This problem, however, requires more empirical research to draw firm conclusions.

The solution lies in the use of evidence from other countries where such studies have been conducted. Provided that conditions in these countries are by and large comparable to those in Bulgaria this would give grounds to expect that such causality may exist here. If certain cause and effect relationships are apparent in many countries, there will be reason to expect that they will apply to Bulgaria too.

One can assume that such a cause and effect relationship exists even though its strength may not be the same. It is important that the dependent variable responds to the changes in the independent variable.

By means of such an analysis we establish a set of production factors that have strong enough impact on productivity and GDP. If the regression analysis proves the existence of a cause and effect link economic policy should focus on activating these production factors.

We consider the following dependent variables: GDP growth, labour productivity growth, total factor productivity growth, economic convergence. The following independent variables are used: investment, available physical and/or human capital, restructuring of the economy, research and development expenditures, public spending from the budget, taxation, inflation, financial development, openness of the national market, deregulation, competition etc.

The analysis gives grounds to assume that economic policy priorities for achieving accelerated development in Bulgaria over the coming decades can be as follows:

-                 maintaining macro-economic stability;

-                 regulation, deregulation, competition and entrepreneurship;

-                 openness of the economy towards global markets;

-                 investment in physical and human capital;

-                 high level of employment and utilisation of working time;

-                 appropriate income policy;

-                 tolerance of social divergence but not of social polarisation;

-                 mitigating the consequences of the demographic crisis;

-                active innovation policy;

-                 break-through science and technology development;

-                 innovation of consumer and production patterns;

-                financial system development and resource mobilisation;

-                 appropriate institutional policies;

-                 efficient environmental policies.

 

2.3.1. Macroeconomic Stability

 

Macroeconomic stability implies stability of both the production and the financial systems. The stability of the production system is the core of the stability of the macroeconomic system. Financial stability is a function of the stability of production. A sustainable financial stability is impossible without sustainable growth. Of course the reverse is also true, but the productive macro- and microsystems and their stability lie at the root of the macroeconomic system and its stability. The cause-effect links between them are two-way, but the impulse from the production to the financial system is dominant.

The financial system ultimately serves the production of wealth and not vice versa. The fundamental goal of production is to meet the needs of the people. Low inflation, a balanced budget, balanced current account, stable exchange rate, currency reserve, etc. are only means to achieve this goal. The ultimate goal of companies is to generate products and services, and not low inflation, a strictly balanced budget or stable exchange rate.

In the coming 20 years Bulgaria should have a price policy that complies with at least three requirements: stability and predictability, an environment appropriate for growth and a gradual convergence to EU price levels. It is obvious that there will be high inflation according to the criteria of the neo-classicists and that this will have an impact on interest rates, income policy and the exchange rate. From this point of view the current low inflation is a defect of the system rather than indicator of long-term stability.

Evaluating the permissible inflation over the next 20 years, we need to take account that this will be a period of convergence to the EU on all important economic indicators including average price and income levels. At a projected average annual inflation in the EU of approximately 2% over the next decades, Bulgaria should allow for average annual inflation of between 8 and 10% to increase the domestic price level about 3 times over 20 years, i.e. to converge with the EU price level.

Economic theory and business practice have proved and the Bulgarian experience over the past decade has confirmed that bringing inflation down to zero is not justified since it has a high economic and social cost. A steady tolerance of forced two-digit unemployment in the name of low one digit inflation has a very high social cost. This is expressed in poor utilisation of the available physical and human capital, paired with growing social and political tension. The total economic, social and political cost to the public is manifold higher than the cost of moderately high inflation accompanied with normal unemployment of about 4-6%.

The economic policy of Bulgaria over the coming decades must strive for the lowest possible unemployment and lowest possible inflation. Ultimately a compromise is necessary instead of sacrificing employment for the sake of low inflation or vice versa. This conclusion is valid for Bulgaria and countries in similar conditions. The conditions in the developed European countries are different including the levels and the relations between inflation and unemployment. The so-called “Phillips’ Curve” and the “misery index”, suggested by A. Okun are used to study this interdependence.

We adhere to a more flexible perception of a balanced budget. Тhis is a budget that is balanced over a longer horizon with permissible annual deviations of up to ±2-3%. In years of economic decline a deficit of a couple of points is permissible whereas in years of high growth a surplus of a couple of points should be maintained. In extreme situations one can allow for higher deficits provided that non-inflationary financing is available and the public indebtedness does not grow to dangerous levels. We do not share the view of strictly balanced budget at any price and any time. Balanced budget is desirable as a means for achieving strategic objectives but strictly balanced budget is not the highest value to a society.

The notion of a balanced current account should also be handled in a flexible manner. A deficit of 4-6% is acceptable in individual years. Deficits can be tolerated for a longer period when the main causes are the import of investment goods and/or other stable sources for compensation are available.

Maintaining a large current account deficit for a long time is dangerous, since it increases external indebtedness and destabilises the budget. This is especially relevant for Bulgaria because of the current high external indebtedness and the imminent large internal spending and imports in preparation for EU accession. One must explore a compromise between these in the name of accelerated growth.

The healthiest way of balancing the current account is boosting competitive exports. This in tern requires measures to upgrade competitiveness. This is the policy to be persued in Bulgaria over the following years and decades. We do not share the present policy to balance the current account mainly through a balanced budget.

The exchange rate will have an important role to play when making these hard decisions. Bulgaria already suffers from the exchange rate peg to the Euro (DM) introduced in July 1997. The pegged rate becomes particularly dangerous with an appreciating Euro, as has been the case lately. If appreciation goes on as it looks like losses will grow to a scale that can hardly be borne in the current state of the economy.

At first glance, losses due to the expensive BGN in the area of exports are balanced by the benefits in imports and external debt service. But the agents who export differ from both these who import and of the budget. The losses incurred by export manufacturers are not compensated to them by the benefits to the importers and to the budget and vice versa. Stagnation and even bankruptcies of exporting companies due to appreciating BGN will jeopardise future revenues to the budget and the current account and hence their stability.

If this persists, the expensive BGN can trigger bankruptcies of exporting companies, can destabilise the economy and suppress growth. This is the cost that Bulgaria is already paying for adhering to a pegged exchange rate. A delay in EU accession beyond 2007, which is not unlikely, would postpone accession to the Economic and Monetary Union. This may have even more severe consequences for businesses and consumers, for instance a shock immediately after accession.

The fiscal and current account policy will determine debt policy to a great extent. The latter should be a policy of a moderate overall indebtedness. On the one hand, Bulgaria needs external investment loans and direct foreign investment for accelerated innovation of production capacities, of infrastructure, for the protection of environment and other areas of activity. On the other hand, one must take consideration of indebtedness. This necessitates looking for compromises, once again for the sake of accelerated growth.

The macroeconomic stability policy in the coming 20 years could be expressed in numerical terms. These are: average annual GDP growth of 5.0-5.5%, reducing unemployment to 4-6% by the end of the period, an average annual inflation of 8-10%, an average annual budget deficit of 1-1.5%, an average annual current account deficit of about 5%, total indebtedness of 50-65% (see table 7.1.).

 

2.3.2. Regulation and Deregulation

 

An accelerated development of the Bulgarian economy over the coming decades is impossible without significant deregulation of the economy. Convergence, however, needs some minimum regulation in the areas where deregulation is not effective as a disciplining mechanism, competition is still weak, legitimate interests of market agents, health and the environment are at stake, as well as where vital national interests must be protected. A modern economy is the one with a high degree of deregulation and regulation that is restricted in scope but efficient.

 

2.3.3. Competition and Types of Property

 

The fundamental principles of mainstream economics assume private property and competition as preconditions for sound economic performance. Neither of them existed in Bulgaria. They are in the process of being established. The emphasis is, however, confined to private property only.

Privatisation as the focus of transformation is being justified with motivation. Privatisation is claimed to be the only mechanism capable of inducing economic motivation for delivering efficient economic activity. This may be true for a small business but is not so for the medium size and large companies where the functions of ownership and management are separated. Privatisation, therefore, is necessary but insufficient for creating an efficient motivational mechanism.

The main driving force nowadays is the quality of management. The managers may or may not be owners. Their income as highly qualified employees (salaries and bonuses) may exceed their income as owners (dividend).

The managers act in a market environment where no one is interested in the specific institutional and corporate makeup of the company that has manufactured a commodity. Only price and quality matter to the buyer. They depend mainly on the competitive environment in which production and sales take place.

International practice offers thousands of examples of well managed state owned companies and of poorly managed private businesses. The reverse is equally true. Companies go into bankruptcy not because of the type of their ownership, but due to poor management. Naturally there is a correlation between the ownership (shareholders) and the quality of management, but it is weaker than the dependence between the competitive environment and quality of management. Even the best private company tends to abuse its monopoly status.

 The relations between shareholders and managers of medium size and large companies and their ability to influence each other have always been complex. In the era of globalisation they are even more complex and the boundaries between them are indistinct. The importance of managers is increasing for the performance of companies in general and particularly of large corporations and multinationals.

The quality of management is impacted also by the pressure of stakeholders – the people working in the company, those living in the neighbourhood, the community, the trade unions, the budget as a tax collector and the social security system as a social security contributions collector. The suppliers of a company and other partners are also interested in its good performance and exercise constructive pressure on its management.

There are no simple, one-way and permanently valid relations in the modern economy. Private property is important, but it is no less important (and is becoming increasingly important) to have a competitive environment. Private property and competition have to complement rather than contradict each other. Relations between the two are relations of mutual complementarity and not of substitution. Competition is a powerful driving force of the modern economy, and so is private property. Splitting them and opposing one to the other impedes the normal functioning of the economy.

A private sector based economy can not develop without competition because private monopoly suffocates it. It “buys” governments and MPs, and sharpens social polarisation. International experience provides numerous examples of socio-economic stagnation and chronic political instability under a total dominance of the private sector but weak state and lack of competition such as in Central and Latin America, Africa and southern Asia.

 

2.3.4. Foreign Economic Policy

 

Openness is a typical feature of the Bulgarian economy, but unlike the economies of the other CEECs it has not shown the necessary adaptability to the requirements of the international markets over the years of transition. The reasons are the imperfections of domestic and foreign economic policies that have delayed development and have had a direct impact on future EU membership. This calls for a policy of accelerated foreign economic development. This policy should provide faster foreign trade growth rates compared to GDP growth, as well as higher growth of GDP than in the other CEE countries.

The future policies in the area of trade liberalisation should be an improved continuation of the current policy. They should contribute to the effective use of existing opportunities for access of Bulgarian products to foreign markets. Policy should be determined by the global trends in international trade and will have to address the existing non-tariff restrictions.

The trade incentive policy boils down to providing incentives for exports as well as for raw material and investment goods imports for the normal operation of export-oriented and related production. The forms and methods of such a policy vary. They depend on the level of industrialisation of the economy and on the international market capacity to absorb competitive Bulgarian exports.

The Bulgarian presence on the international markets is directly related to the policy on inward foreign investment. It must focus in the coming years on lifting the formal restrictions and administrative barriers for foreign capital, on using a system of guarantees that takes into account the specifics of the foreign investment process and compensates for the delays caused by the distortions in the investment climate. The availability of an effective institutional apparatus is essential.

Foreign economic policy predetermines the state of the balance of payments. The policy over the coming years should be directed at maintaining a reasonable current account deficit of approximately 5%. A similar policy should be implemented with respect to foreign indebtedness at levels of 70 to 50% of GDP.

The relations between Bulgarian and foreign companies are the core of these developments. They have to be promoted by intensive innovation activities. Bulgaria’s expected EU membership determines the specifics of the trade in agricultural and industrial goods.

The policy of providing export incentives will cover the application of various financial measures (export subsidies, export credit, state guarantees to export credits, tax relief and custom duty exemptions) as well as non-financial measures (information services, consulting services, direct export incentives, training and publications, missions, fairs, visits of trade partners).

 

2.3.5. Policy for Savings and Investment in Physical Capital

 

The Bulgarian economic policy faces two major challenges: a modest savings and investment domestic potential and insufficient attractiveness of the country for foreign investment.

Effective policies are needed to increase domestic savings. This can be done by gradually increasing income, creating an appropriate business environment for the corporate sector. Positive real interest rates on deposits and security yields, smaller deposit and loan interest spreads, greater diversification and effectiveness of savings instruments, an improved deposit protection and a higher share of long-term deposits and securities would also contribute to this end.

Consolidation of the banking system is necessary. Improved transparency of the performance of the banking and non-banking financial institutions is needed. Faster development of non-banking institutions; enhancing competition between banking and other financial institutions; improving banking supervision; better protection for minority shareholders; tax exemptions on dividends etc. are also indispensable

Bulgaria needs higher public savings. This can be achieved by significantly improving tax and non-tax revenue collection, maintaining a moderate budget deficit in years of stagnation and a budget surplus in years of high growth, as well as an increase of budget investments in infrastructure.

Preferred external sources for savings in the future will include transfers from pre-accession, and later - from structural and other EU funds, remittances from Bulgarians working abroad, FDI, European capital markets and foreign investment borrowing. A prospective form of attracting strategic investors can be the establishment of high-tech facilities in Bulgaria jointly with leading multinational companies employing skilled Bulgarian staff.

The state must also make use of depreciation to stimulate investment activity. The share of depreciation in the production costs in Bulgaria is low and has been reduced to a symbolic level over the recent years. Fixed assets must undergo a revaluation. Depreciation rates are too low. An update of fixed asset values combined with an increase of depreciation rates and a greater flexibility in their application are needed. Depreciation rates in the high-tech sectors have to be increased significantly.

As a direct participant in the investment process the government has an important role to play in increasing investment activity particularly in infrastructure. The government can be a sole investor in isolated cases, but will usually work together with Bulgarian and foreign private capital. The government can also invest jointly with Bulgarian and foreign private capital in attractive high tech facilities that are of particular importance to the national economy.

Investor incentives should be announced in advance and remain valid for a longer period – 10 years and longer.

We recommend tentative targets on saving and investment. Here are the most important: an overall savings rate of 32-33% and an investment rate of 36-37%, share of investment in infrastructure – 40%, share of investment in ICT – 18-19% of the total, import of investment goods – 35% of total imports by 2020. An increase of the share of investment for up to date services and in reconstruction and innovation is also recommended (see table 8.1.).

 

2.3.6. Human Capital Development Policy

 

The most important conclusions based on international experience in education are:

-  The educational level of parents has a very strong influence on the results of their children’s education.

-  There is no strong correlation between education expenditures and teaching quality.

-  Centralised exams provide incentives for a high quality of teaching.

-  Centralised drafting of curricula is to be preferred, whereas distribution of available resources, hiring, appointment, promotion and firing of teachers, internal organisation etc. should be the responsibility of school management.

-  Giving rights and initiative to individual teachers is useful, whereas wide scale rights of teacher’s unions do not contribute to improving the quality of education.

-  Competition between public and private schools encourages high quality teaching and saving of resources in both systems.

The economic and social convergence of Bulgaria to the EU is impossible without convergence of human capital in both quantitative and qualitative terms. Bulgaria can not prosper without a modern system of education. The authorities tend to neglect this obvious truth.

The participation of the state in maintaining the health, education and skills of the citizens is of fundamental importance for Bulgaria’s development. The state should involve the private sector but these very important and delicate matters that go far beyond commercial interest can’t be entrusted entirely to the private sector. Measures for health and education do not bring about results quickly and are largely outside the scope of the private enterprise.

Until recently education and qualification were synonymous with primary, secondary and higher education. In the circumstances of an accelerated development and in the environment of integration and globalisation, the meaning of this concept becomes wider and deeper.

Complex literacy is needed nowadays. This means reading and writing in the native language; solid foreign language skills; computer and Internet literacy, ability for individual and team work; analytical skills; communication skills; independence in learning and in life.

A fundamental concern of the state should be to secure access to healthcare and education for all citizens. Depriving the poor and their children of healthcare and education deprives the society of people who may prove to be great talents. And more importantly, it deprives many Bulgarians of a fundamental human right – the right to life, health and knowledge.

In the absence of state intervention, economic polarisation leads to social polarisation that nurtures educational polarisation. It intensifies digital devide, which in turn deepens social and economic polarisation.

Without state intervention and EU assistance the polarisation processes can become even more dangerous for Bulgaria due to the severe economic situation and the current state of education. The absence of measures in this area will make accelerated development impossible. Educational polarisation, coupled with deterioration of quality of education may have grave long-term consequences for the Bulgarian economy and the society at large.

The deepening educational polarisation and leaving the problem of complex literacy unresolved harbours the danger of leaving Bulgaria at the economic, social and intellectual periphery of Europe, as is the case nowadays. No accelerated development is possible in such an environment.

Education requires large resources – public and private financing, professional expertise, technical and other infrastructure, subsidies for the municipalities, support by the parents. The result depends on the size of the expenditures but also on their composition and management.

The strategy recommends that the expenditures of Bulgaria for education grow from 3.8% of GDP in 2000 to 6.5-7.5% in 2010 and 8-9% by 2020. The intention is that the cumulative education of the population within the 15 to 65 age bracket should grow from 8.4 years per capita in 2000 to 10 years in 2010 and 11.5 by 2020 (see table 4.5.).

What matters in this case is not only the numerical level but also its composition – primary, secondary and higher education. Strictly speaking these components are not commensurate. The weighted indicator, reflecting the levels of education is preferable.

Financial allocations for education are very important but they should not be exaggerated. Larger public spending does not automatically lead to better quality of education. Prior to providing additional resources to the education system, it has to be rationalised. Only then will resources be used in an effective manner.

The larger part of education expenditures in Bulgaria is provided by the state. This is also the case in the EU countries. The dominant role of the state in this area must continue. This function can be performed in various ways. The most widely used is and will be the financing of public schools, which spend the funds according to certain rules.

An increasing number of individuals and families will be offered resources in the form of education credits under favourable terms, grants, special education vouchers by means of which the holders can choose a school or other specialised training establishment. Such voucher schemes will be available for training and retraining of the unemployed. Special deposits for future education with tax exempt interest will be an option to be considered for introduction.

The distribution of educational subsidies among pre-school, primary, secondary, higher education and post-graduate learning is also important. Bulgaria has no experience in this area, particularly with life-long learning. More resources compared with those to date must be allocated to financing pre-school and primary education, which have been internationally proven as the most effective and have long lasting consequences over the follow-up phases of education.

Particular attention must be given to improvements in the quality of education, which is mediocre and deteriorating. The minds of Bulgarian students must become thinking machines and not depositories for facts, dates and numbers, which they may never need.

The state should develop an appropriate scheme to provide incentives to older workers and professionals to further their qualifications in the official educational system or outside it. Ideas for implementing this recommendation are given in the main text of the study.

Nowadays there are two parallel processes: First, the growing need for complex literacy. Second, deteriorating access to complex knowledge. One of the great problems for Bulgaria is the growing tension between the two conflicting processes. This is growing with the polarisation of the access of citizens to ICT and particularly Internet and of small and medium size companies to e-commerce and other areas of ICT compared with large companies.

There is a gap between the composition of the educated in terms of professions and skills and the market demand even in the advanced economies. This gap is much larger in Bulgaria and will grow with the progress of the information society. That will make it more difficult for workers and professionals to find appropriate employment and for the companies to find appropriate workers and professionals.

Schools, being the only establishments that have provided education so far in Bulgaria, should become part of a wider system for training, called “life-long learning for all”. School is no longer the beginning and the end of education but a very important link of the overall system of life-long learning.

In today’s environment graduation from upper secondary school or a vocational school becomes a necessity for long-term employment. About 80-85% of young people in the EU have such an education. This too is an important prerequisite for developing of life-long learning of young people who do not continue in universities. Secondary school will play the same role for the life-long learning of these young people as that, which universities will play for their graduates.

The situation in Bulgaria is not favourable in this respect. It is today not merely far removed from the system of life-long learning, but has deteriorated compared to the past achievements in both education and training of workers and professionals. The damage must be remedied quickly.

A system is needed to encourage employees and employers to constantly improve the skills of the personnel as well as to align and protect their interests. This system must incorporate state support, state guaranteed diploma for the respective level of qualifications that the worker can use for all employers. A system of allocations for training in a personal account for each employee, similar to depreciation allowances for fixed assets, is needed. Targeted deposits for future training, tax exemptions for education and training expenses, a system of mutual obligations of the employer and the employee related to education and training could also be helpful.

Retaining human capital is as important as investing in it. Emigration of young and other professionals is one of the most dangerous channels draining human capital. Bulgaria along with other CEECs will be subjected to intellectual and biological depletion in this respect in the coming years and decades.

The brain drain is not a simple phenomenon. It has both positive and negative dimensions. The most important part of the brain drain problem for the sending countries is restricting or at least mitigating it. Some recommend forceful administrative measures. This approach is not acceptable nowadays due to obvious political, economic, social and moral reasons.

The healthiest solution of the problem is the accelerated economic and social development, the improvement of living conditions and professional opportunities in Bulgaria. The young people and other highly qualified professionals would not leave such an environment. This is, however, a very complex process and its results can be expected no earlier than 15-20 years from now.

Although difficult to implement, other solutions are also possible. Modest results can be expected in the medium to long term (5-10 years). Ideas for such solutions are presented in the main text of the study.

For some quantitative outlines of the proposed strategy please refer to table 4.5 of the main text.

 

2.3.7. Employment Enhancement Policy

 

We expect important changes on the labour market. The issues of employment in the first decade will differ from those in the second and later periods. The main challenge in the first decade will be to reduce unemployment, increase the qualification of the work force and mitigate the consequences of emigration of skilled personnel.

In the second decade and beyond, the main challenge will be facing the consequences of the demographic crisis. They are evident even now, but are not felt as strongly due to the business contraction and high unemployment. The Bulgarian authorities must prepare for a very different employment policy in the second decade and beyond. This preparation should start now.

There are numerous European Commission papers on increasing employment and improvement of working time utilisation. There is also a European Employment Strategy the foundations of which were laid in 1997. It incorporates four clearly defined large-scale modernisation projects in that area, known as the 4 pillars of the Strategy: ability to work, entrepreneurship, adaptation, forms of organisation of labour and higher qualification, equal opportunities for all citizens. This is a change in the paradigm, not simply another rationalisation.

The preparation of Bulgaria for accession and particularly the time after accession demands that all activities in this area be oriented towards meeting the requirements of the European Employment Strategy.

This strategy proposes policies and measures to resolve the most severe problems of employment and unemployment.

In the first stage (until 2007) a reinvigorating of economic policy is necessary through which the conditions for large-scale job creation for permanent employment will be established. Additional investment of 2.0-2.5 billion BGN per annum can secure 85,000-100,000 new permanent jobs. Along with this, medium-term policy should target a decrease of the officially recorded unemployment from 17% to 13%, an increase in employment from 41% to 45%, and in economic activity from 50% to 52-53%.

The currently recorded low unemployment level in Bulgaria (considered a world record in terms of speed of decrease) does not reflect reality. The very fact that it is a world record raises suspicion. Firstly, it was achieved by the “creation” of 80,000-100,000 new jobs mainly for municipal roadside cleaning for which more than 200 million BGN is disbursed every year, instead of producing sustainable products or services. This is a strongly distorted (and ineffective) form of active employment policy. Had these people been employed into production, they could have contributed to an almost double-digit GDP growth, which is, however, non-existent in official statistics. Second, it does not take into consideration the over 20% of labour force dropouts – the so-called “discouraged unemployed”.

The second stage (2007-2010) will require a better co-ordination of economic and social policy in order to increase employment to 48%; reduce unemployment to 10-12%; and achieve economic activity of 54-56%;

In the third stage (2010-2020) the employment policy and the efforts against unemployment will have to be aligned with the goals, the acquis communautaire and the social practices of the European Union. Unemployment is expected to recede to 4-6%, employment to increase to 61-62% and the economically active population to reach 63-65% towards the end of the period

The priority areas on which employment and unemployment policies should focus are listed in the main text.

 

2.3.8. Income Policy

 

Income policy continues to be based on the residual principle. It is illogically restrictive and has an anti-inflationary focus in spite of the fact that salaries have not been inflation drivers in Bulgaria for a long time. Salaries, pensions and other guaranteed personal income, as well as the real disposable income of households are losing their purchasing power. Consumption is shrinking. Bulgaria is among the poorest countries in Europe.

Poverty has struck the prevailing part of the population - 43-47% of households live in extreme poverty, 35-40% balance the family budget at the cost of drastic deprivations, 10-12% do not suffer any serious deprivation and 1-3% are well off.

Based on the analysis of the present situation, priority areas for income policy until 2020 have been outlined in the main text.

We suggest four scenarios for increasing salaries and pensions.

According to the optimistic scenario, the real average monthly salary should grow by 11% on average per annum from 225 BGN in 2000 to over 1,800 BGN by 2020(see table 4.4.). According to the same scenario, the real average monthly pension will grow by 13% per annum and will increase from 100 BGN in 2000 to 1150 in 2020 (see table 4.7).

These scenarios are formulated on the basis of the optimistic scenarios for GDP growth – 5.0- 5.5% annual average until 2020 (see table 4.1 and chart 4.1.).

Specific proposals are made for the income policy, as well as measures that the government has to undertake along with the social partners at the respective stages

 

2.3.9. Mitigating the Consequences of the Demographic Crisis

 

The demographic crisis in Bulgaria is deteriorating rapidly. It will be one of the most serious challenges in the coming decades. This crisis coincides and even exceeds similar problems in Western Europe in spite of an economic and social development, which lags that of Western Europe by 40-50 years. The current demographic problems in Western Europe are, according to claims of its analysts, the result of a demographic maturity. In Bulgaria they are the fallout of a state of crisis. Hence, we are decades behind in terms of social and economic development and decades ahead in terms of the manifestations of this crisis.

Providing highly qualified labour with higher and upper secondary education is a priority. These are people who will satisfy the growing need for such skills, particularly in the second decade and beyond. The problem is more complicated considering the low birth rate and the decreasing number of people entering into an employable age. The smaller numbers have to be made up for by a better quality of labour and new technologies.

А large scale substitution of insufficient labour with more capital of a better quality is necessary. Preparation for this substitution must start now. Bulgaria will not be able to sustain its accelerated development unless this substitution takes place soon. Resolving this problem will be complicated even further if a significant number of qualified young professionals emigrate in the next 5-10 years. The healthy solution is in creating an attractive environment for them to remain in.

Other measures are needed in the older age groups to mitigate the lack of labour of high and mid level qualification. One option could be to increase labour participation and employment rates in the age group between 25 and 54 years.

Measures are needed to increase labour participation and employment in the 55-64 age group. This can be done by means of training and retraining, life-long learning, abolishing the incentives for early retirement, introducing incentives for a greater working age and disincentives for early retirement as well as preparations for a gradual increase of the official retirement age.

One must opt for a cautious increase in the retirement age. This requires early measures for improving living and working conditions, healthcare, life-long learning measures and the transition to an “active old age”. Given the current difficult living and working conditions, increasing the pension age would be impossible since people at that age already suffer physiological and mental exhaustion.

These measures can be used for the 65+ age group in order to encourage them to stay on the labour market for longer. One can introduce further incentives and support in terms of gradual retirement from active labour activity by combining work with rest, a wider application of part-time employment, work from home, consultancy over the Internet etc. in addition to the measures already mentioned. This will be possible in the second, particularly in the third decade and beyond, when a significant growth of life expectancy and an overall improvement of the general health of the elderly are expected.

One of the consequences of the demographic crisis is the deterioration of the ratio between employed and unemployed. In this country it is one of the most unfavourable in Europe at approximately 0.8:1 (which also includes the people working in the shadow economy) and is deteriorating. In the EU countries the ratio between employed and unemployed is three times higher.

An analysis of the composition of the employed and of the unemployed raises additional concerns. This is because the share of the young and the students is shrinking, the share of adults is growing and the share of the long-term unemployed is very high (see table 4.7). The number of retirees in Bulgaria compared to the employed was 2.5-3.0 times higher than the EU average in 2000.

The ratio between the young and the elderly working people will deteriorate in the second decade and beyond. Given the current rate of the demographic crisis and the lack of action by the authorities there are no reasons to expect any stabilisation, and even less so an improvement in the unemployed group.

The ageing оf the Bulgarian work force is becoming more and more apparent. In the future it will be accompanied with an upward movement of the retirement age. On the one hand, the share of the young people in the work force, the groups under 25 and fewer than 35 years will fall. On the other hand, the share of the working people between 55 and 64 years and above 64 will grow. Toward the end of the second and particularly in the 3rd and the 4th decade, with the expected increase of life expectancy (75—77 years for men and 80-82 for women) the share of the working people older than 65 will grow.

This sets new problems for Bulgaria. A mass introduction of the life-long learning will have to be accelerated, particularly for the work force of the middle aged and elderly generation. This is because the enhanced development of science and technology speeds up the ageing of knowledge. By 2015-2020 the major part of present knowledge of the work force will be obsolete. This fact speaks for the scale of the challenge. It will require radical changes in the education system and in training outside it. The life-long learning system will become increasingly important.

The quality of services will have to be improved. This is particularly needed in healthcare, nurseries and kindergartens, for primary education and for the further levels of education, for care for the elderly, for transport and many other services.

Significant changes are needed in the organisation of production and labour because the working patterns of people in the 25-40, 50-60 and above the 65-70 age groups differ. Flexible labour systems will increasingly be applied.

Labour productivity will grow due to an increasingly active substitution of labour with modern capital. The proportions will usually be non-traditional, due to the novel qualities of future labour and technologies. This exchange will also be activated in work from home. In the absence of this it will be impossible to raise the standards for the effective and healthy work capability.

The ageing of the population is exerting stronger pressure on public finances. It will grow in the coming decades due to larger number of pensioners, larger average pension, additional costs of healthcare and other services for the elderly. We estimate that additional expenditure of 6.5-7.5 percentage points of GDP will be needed by 2020. This has to be added to the 8% registered in 2000 (see table 4.7). Judging by the experience of the EU member states the additional expenditures may be even higher than this estimate.

Stabilising public finances is also a priority task for Bulgaria against the background of the growing demographic pressure. This task will be very difficult considering the incredibly low level of pensions and the imperative need for their increase. One could add to this the danger of shocks (bankruptcies and other collapses) in the private pension funds, the large public debt and the necessity for an active budget policy for EU accession. The expected burden of pension expenditures, about 13-15% of GDP by 2020, will be very severe indeed.

A labour market reform is needed to achieve higher employment. This will improve the ratio between employed and unemployed, will boost growth, budget revenues and improve the policy response to the problems of an ageing population. It will be useful to reduce general income taxation for people with lower salaries. It would be appropriate to abstain from increases in social security contributions and to explore opportunities for their reduction, mainly by means of improving collection and restricting shadow employment. The system for life-long learning can also contribute to the increase of employment levels.

Pension reform improvements are also essential. The reforms initiated in Bulgaria are correct in principle. They must, however, be improved in some important areas. One must seek fairer social balance between intergenerational interests. Bulgaria must aim at two to threefold higher replacement ratio over the next years and decades.

Gradual increases in the pension age must be prepared, which goes together with providing the option to continue work to all that chose to do so. This will be harder to apply while there is high unemployment, but will become essential after 2015-2020 when this problem will be resolved and the consequences of the demographic crisis become more severe.

As already stated the increase of the pension age must be preceded by a significant improvement of living and working conditions as well as an increase in average life expectancy. Prior to creating such prerequisites the emphasis should be set on creating incentives for people who are willing to continue working in their pension age and discouraging early retirement.

Some Western countries recommend reducing future pensions with the view of budget savings. This, in addition to being politically difficult, is wrong for Bulgaria due to the prevalence of low pensions. Bulgaria’s problem in the coming years will be to improve the ratio of pre-retirement income (average salary) and post-retirement income (average pension) by significantly increasing the latter.

Reducing the number of pensioners rather than reducing pensions can mitigate the budgetary burden in Bulgaria. This could be achieved by giving pensioners an opportunity to work after retirement age and even encouraging them to do so.

The budgetary and the social security system’s stability in the coming years and decades will also depend on the stability of the voluntary retirement and health contributions to private funds. Their stability is important, considering that it affects the interests of hundreds of thousands of people contributing to private funds. Shocks in this area can be prevented by more effective public supervision of the management of these funds.

No single measure can resolve the problem. The stability of the budget and of the social security system in the conditions of an ageing population can only be resolved by means of a complex set of interrelated measures. High growth will be central to this.

There are frequent references to mitigating the consequences of the demographic crisis in Bulgaria. There is a silent agreement that the demographic crisis is an inevitable exogenous process. This is hardly the case. Unlike Western Europe and Japan, the demographic crisis in Bulgaria is not a result of demographic maturity, but of a social and economic crisis. Overcoming this crisis should alienate the demographic crisis.

It would be appropriate to entrust experts with devising a strategy for mitigating the demographic crisis in Bulgaria. To recapitulate: mitigation of the very demographic crisis rather than its consequences is a fundamental strategic objective for Bulgaria. Rapid and radical action is indispensable because if current trends are left unchecked the demographic destiny of Bulgaria will be at stake in the next 50-70 years. Lack of action in demographic policy may have severe strategic consequences for Bulgaria within this century. This is due to the rapid decline in Bulgaria’s population. It amounted to 8.95 million in 1985 and 7.85 million in 2002. It is projected to be about 6.2 million in 2025 and less than 4 million in 2050, i.e. at the level of 1900.

 

2.3.10. Alleviating Social Polarisation and Alienation

 

Bulgaria has the highest social polarisation in CEE – a Gini coefficient of 0.41. It is higher only in the CIS countries.

No accelerated development is possible given such social polarisation. Successful development in a country of 7.8 million people is unthinkable when 2.5 million are doomed to severe poverty and are isolated from the benefits of human civilisation. This is not due to the state’s insufficient financial resources but mainly to the irrational in economic and social terms distribution of these resources. A small minority of 1-3% appropriates in criminal and semi-criminal ways a part of wealth that is much larger than their contribution to its generation and in doing so deprives the majority from their share. The government not only tolerates, but also by withholding active measures, contributes to the increase of income polarisation.

The state has ignored the poor and unemployed and has isolated them for more than a decade. They have responded with total alienation and growing hostility to the state and society. There can be no normal social and economic development and civil peace in such a society, let alone any accelerated sustainable development. World experience over the past century as well as the comparative analysis of the social and economic development of Africa and Southeast Asia over the past 50 years has proved this.

Alleviating social polarisation by means of changing distribution relations and inclusion of the alienated is one of the most important measures, which the Bulgarian government must address immediately. This, however, can not be done quickly because of the large scale of poverty and the weakened statehood.

Accelerated social and economic development implies encouraging income divergence, based on contribution by labour, capital and entrepreneurship of various groups, but restricting social polarisation.

No less important is the economic effect of alleviating social polarisation. According to rough estimates criminal activity deprives the budget of at least 2.0-2.5 billion BGN per annum (7.5-8.5% of GDP).

With such additional revenues the state can afford further cuts in taxes and social security contributions and incentives for business activity; higher investments in infrastructure, healthcare, education, science, environmental protection etc. They, for their part, will result in additional GDP growth, more resources for the development of regional communities, for modernising the system of government. There would be additional resources for increasing pensions and improving healthcare for the elderly, for law enforcement and the judiciary, for maintaining relative budget balance by improved financing of the sectors that provide critical public services.

Fair distribution provides more adequate social and working climate. People tend to work more conscientiously and be more productive in such an environment. They feel that they are contributing to important national goals. This also helps accelerate economic and social development.

Continuous action and application of complex economic, social and other measures is needed. Measures to achieve this goal are recommended in the main text of the study.

 

2.3.11. Economic Aspects of Innovation Policy

 

Bulgaria’s internal innovation potential is restricted. It can provide no more than 10-15% of the core technological and other innovations it needs for economic and social development in the next two decades. The main source for technological and other innovations will be FDI, import of investment goods, projects and contacts with foreign experts, import of know-how, scholarships for Bulgarian scientists and other professionals abroad.

Bulgaria must be prepared. This calls for accelerated development of education, of applied sciences, of research and development, as well as first steps in marketing new technologies. Bulgaria will be unable to absorb, disseminate and use imported innovations without certain minimum of innovation potential. This will be the main role of Bulgarian innovation policy in the coming years and decades.

The state innovation policy can assist in establishing proactive innovation development in many areas: development of an appropriate set of economic incentives for innovation activity (subsidies, tax relief, etc.), developing research in public research institutes, establishments of higher education and subsidising research in private research establishments. The same applies to help increasing the efficiency and the scale of private investment in innovation, supporting effective working relations among the participants in the innovation system, simplifying regulation where necessary and maximising deregulation of everything else in innovation activities.

The establishment and development of hi-tech innovation enterprises and of small regional research and development facilities must be encouraged. The initiation of strategic alliances between Bulgarian high-tech innovation companies and foreign high-tech companies must be facilitated.

The government can use various instruments to encourage innovation activity. The most important of these are: state subsidies for funding public research and development facilities, state subsidies for private research and development facilities, tax relief for public and private research and development, participation in venture financing and providing credits for innovative operations. The same applies to training personnel for innovative operations, creating an appropriate general and innovative infrastructure, effective protection of intellectual property, facilitating contacts between R&D and production companies. Simplifying the legal and economic framework for innovative activities, facilitating imports of foreign technical and other innovations, facilitating contacts between Bulgarian and foreign innovation companies could also be helpful.

Funding of public innovation facilities must be increased. These are public research institutes, laboratories, research operations of state universities, state research and development facilities and, in some cases, state owned enterprises, which develop important technological and other innovations.

The state has to provide subsidies for important research projects, implemented by private innovation companies. This can be done in the form of low interest loans, tax and other relief as well as state guarantees on loans of private contractors. The difference between the interest on the targeted loan and the market interest rate should be covered by the state. Maximum transparency is essential in these cases, which can potentially be provided by means of public tenders and through other guarantees against abuse.

Special attention should be devoted when allocating state funding to research projects of great medium and long-term importance where Bulgaria has a significant scientific track record. In these cases results can be achieved alone or in co-operation with foreign partners in small niches but on a global scale and of great importance to Bulgarian science and, in the long-term, to the national economy. It is only fair to apply a special regime for funding such projects; ensure support for setting up the facilities and flexibility in paying the remuneration of researchers. Talented researchers should be paid very high remuneration.

When providing subsidies for public and private innovation activity, one must seek appropriate trade-offs between government subsidies and company resources. This is particularly relevant for private innovation companies, so as not to crowd out private investment. One must target a ratio of financing sources that guarantees the complementarity of public and private investment which avoids their mutual substitution. Business practice in developed countries proves that the share of government investment should not exceed 25-30% of total investment in the respective innovation projects.

Public expenditures for innovations will most probably prevail in the next 5-7 years while the share of private expenditures will grow. Judging by the experience of developed countries, the two sources will reach equal shares by 2010 and by 2015-2020 private expenditure would account for 60-70% of the total.

Public funding will remain significant for a long time due to the weakness of private research facilities in Bulgaria and their focus on highly profitable projects with short payback periods. Activities of longer-term significance, particularly those where private sector benefits are much lower than the public benefits should be funded by the state as they are not attractive to the private sector. Such projects are valuable to society and must be financed.

Innovation projects in the area of defence, healthcare, environment protection and fundamental research will be a prerogative of the state for many years to come for obvious reasons. The same applies to high-risk innovation investment. These can attract private resources but must be supported by state participation and/or state guarantees. If not, private capital will avoid high-risk projects.

Funding of innovation activities and particularly public funding is needed not only for direct technological and other solutions that lead to the creation of products of short and medium-term importance. It is even more important for Bulgaria’s preparation to absorb and implement imported innovations and become a part of the international innovation networks. Countries with low innovation activity are not capable of understanding and using imported technical and other innovations. It is essential that Bulgaria does not remain a passive observer of the global innovation processes. To prevent this from happening we recommend a significant increase in research expenditures from 0.5% of GDP in 2000 to 1.4% in 2010 and 2.5% by 2020 (see table 4.5).

Project financing of science and research must be increased to cover all appropriate activities within a couple of years. Theoretical studies of long-term importance should be financed along the established model.

Differentiated payment of researchers based on their contribution must be introduced and remuneration according to degrees, ranks and years of service and attendance during working hours should gradually be abandoned. This will increase the effectiveness of research and development and will release excess personnel.

It is appropriate to create legal provisions for tax exemption of income and profit derived from innovation activities for 10 years or longer. This should be valid for all investors, starting from the initiation of new innovation activity. The same should apply for dividend on capital invested in innovation activity.

Tax relief and direct subsidies for innovation activity should be used both as complementary and mutually substitutable tools. This should be done in a co-ordinated manner to avoid misapplication of these levers.

It is recommended to devise a strategy for development of Bulgarian science, by selecting an appropriate structure for research including fundamental and applied research as well as R&D activities. Efforts should focus on several important areas where we already have or can achieve a significant scientific track record. Co-operation should be sought with foreign research institutions for joint research and marketing in these areas.

A co-ordination mechanism should be established for public funded research and development with a view to allocating restricted resources to areas and projects of prime significance. Public subsidies for research should be distributed on this basis through a tender. It is also advisable to have co-ordination between public and private research operations on a voluntary basis.

A new institutional structure, new organisation of work, new evaluation and remuneration system for researchers is a must. Their pay is humiliatingly low at present. It must be improved dramatically as soon as possible.

 

2.3.12. Economic Dimensions of Break-through Science and Technology Developments

 

In the coming years and decades the economic development of Bulgaria will be most strongly impacted on the macroeconomic and sectoral level by the technologies for general use – information and communication technologies (ICT), biotechnology, new materials, new energy sources, environmentally friendly technologies etc., and on sectoral level – sector technologies. Nanotechnology is expected to have such an impact on a global scale, but it is premature to expect a significant impact on Bulgaria before 2015-2020.

For this to happen highly qualified professionals knowledgeable both in ICT and biotechnology and in ICT and nanotechnology must be trained. There will also be a great demand for managers and entrepreneurs in those areas.

Bulgaria has to design a long-term strategy for the development of information society in the spirit of the European strategy and the Action Plan in this area. For some quantitative outlines of this strategy see table 4.6.

The strategy should be of an imitative (converging) and not of an innovative (leading) nature since imitative solutions are easier and cheaper (approximately 65%) than the innovative ones. Innovative solutions are of course welcome, but Bulgaria has no capacities to make them a main goal. By 2020 the strategy has to aim at closing part of the gap between Bulgaria and the advanced countries in this area. Matching the science and technology level of these countries is not a realistic goal for Bulgaria in the coming decades and even in the distant future.

The imitative approach should dominate Bulgarian science and technology development in the coming decades, combined with an innovative approach in selected niches, where we have already achieved or can accumulate the necessary critical minimum of scientific experience. Bulgaria can, under favourable internal and external conditions, achieve converging development based on the imitative approach over the coming decades and towards the middle of the century. This, however, is not guaranteed and has an equivalent chance of failure.

A more ambitious objective, catching up the levels of the advanced countries by the middle of the century, would be unrealistic. This is unlikely considering that over this long period there are bound to be negative internal and external surprises, which will create additional difficulties for the development of Bulgaria. In this respect, even the proposed speed of the imitative approach contains a significant degree of optimism.

It is hardly possible and necessary to start producing information and communication equipment in Bulgaria. This would be very difficult and costly for a small underdeveloped country. International experience demonstrates that the economy and society can successfully use ICT hardware without producing it. This has been proved by almost all small and medium size nations, including some in the highly developed ones.

ICT development creates new challenges for education and training. On the one hand, the technical means of ICT become an integral part of training personnel. On the other, these developments demand for a new kind of personnel, with new knowledge, new thinking and a new approach to problem solving. This goes beyond training people to use new ICT equipment and speak its language.

Teaching them how to use the information received through ICT in their daily life and work is even more important and difficult. There are major problems related to training appropriate ICT trainers. This all necessitates a strategic rethinking of the system of education and training. This is the way in which society can derive maximum benefit from the great potential of ICT.

Increasing digital literacy is of great importance not only for the people directly involved in sectors like ICT manufacturing, software development and information and communication infrastructure. It is essential to all. The same is true for overcoming digital devide.

Bulgaria is facing very serious problems in this area. On the one hand, the quality of ICT training has been insufficient and has even deteriorated recently. On the other hand, the best graduates of the education system in ICT leave and seek career opportunities in the developed countries, which have special programmes for attracting highly qualified experts in this area. And thirdly, it is unclear how Bulgaria will fill these gaps due to the poor training of Bulgarian experts, the large scale emigration of the highly-skilled and the growing need for such expertise. Regardless of the official statements praising ICT’s importance, it will remain wishful thinking if human resources of high quality are not trained for its development.

A long-term strategy for the development of biotechnology in the spirit of the European strategy and Action Plan on these matters is also necessary for Bulgaria. An outline of such a strategy is provided in the main text.

Bulgaria needs also a concept on the development of some limited research on nanotechnology.

 

2.3.13. Consumer Patterns and Consumption Policy

 

Despite the two-way link between production and consumption, production ultimately exists to satisfy consumption, and not for its own sake. Without effective demand the manufacturing of goods and services becomes meaningless. This demand transforms the manufactured items into useful products – goods.

Consumption is the raison d’etre of production. The reverse is also true of course. However, the fact that a product must first be manufactured in order to be consumed is insufficient for claiming that in terms of importance manufacturing dominates over consumption. A more demanding consumption exercises strong pressure for improvement of manufacturing.

Significant quantitative as well as qualitative adjustments in consumption are expected to take place over the next 20 years. They will be pre-determined by the growing income, the life style changes and the related changes in personal consumption as well as by the deepening demographic crisis. The share of food and beverage consumption in the composition of the household budget will decrease. The share of expenditure on clothing and footwear will stabilise or decrease. The share of housing, furnishing and heating, transport and communications, health, education, travel and recreation expenditures will grow (see table 4.4.).

The quality of consumption will rise. It will become less and less tangible. Knowledge-based consumption will develop rapidly. The share of consumption by the elderly will grow and its composition will change. Personalisation of products and services will grow. The importance of sustainable consumption will also grow. Provided that social polarisation decreases simultaneously. Maintaining or increasing social polarisation will have a reverse effect and will set Bulgaria apart from the global trends in this area.

Theory and practice confirm that mass production is more efficient than individualised, small and medium-scale production. However, it is evident from the above that the trend in the coming decades will be to give up some types of mass production and return to personalised production by age, social, professional and other groups, and in specific cases, on special order for well to do individuals.

At the same time competition will press for greater efficiency. That would require additional effort on the part of scientists and manufacturers to combine large series with the preferences of a group or an individual, possibly by using modular systems or other methods. Flexible automated systems of production may yet again receive greater attention. The other option would be a significant increase of the efficiency of the individual, small- and medium-series production that allows for a combination of personalisation and competitiveness.

The criteria for efficiency and competitiveness will change аs satisfying special personal and group needs with high quality and strict health-related requirements become more important than production cost. The role of quality and health considerations as competitive criteria will grow at the expense of production cost and price. Naturally, competition will exercise pressure for reducing the cost per quality unit and per unit of health effect. The new technologies and methods of organisational set ups will contribute to this.

All this has already led to changes in the consumer policies of the developed countries. The EU promulgated a new strategy for consumer policy 2002-2006. It emphasises the importance of competition, high quality, health safety and personal security of the goods and services offered on the market. Such a consumer policy will become increasingly important for Bulgaria. It will have to facilitate the convergence of the quality of Bulgarian products and health standards to those in Europe.

Against this background and in the context of further development of the EU single market the gradual convergence of prices for products and services to the EU level becomes increasingly important for Bulgaria. They are approximately three times lower than in the advanced European countries. The speed of increase of the average price level in Bulgaria has to exceed significantly the respective process in the EU.

This in turn is related to income policy. Nominal and real income growth in Bulgaria must exceed the growth of average income in the EU. A higher growth of labour productivity is indispensable as well (see table 4.2.). In order to achieve it accelerated economic development is a must.

Two scenarios are likely for such price convergence – gradual and shock. Gradual convergence is possible if controlled pre-emptive increase of prices and nominal incomes in Bulgaria compared to the same processes in the EU is initiated immediately. Guided by this, we recommend an average annual increase of prices of 8-10% and an even faster increase of income by 2020 (see tables 4.4.-4.7. and 7.1.).

If the above scenario was not implemented shock convergence will occur at the time of accession and in the successive years regardless of the will of Bulgarian authorities. This can have a destructive effect on the socio-economic stability in Bulgaria. The first scenario is, therefore, preferable.

The convergence of prices is related to the currency board arrangement with its inherent low inflation and fixed exchange rate, which make the convergence of Bulgarian prices and income to these in the EU impossible. Bulgarian politicians tend to disregard these problems in spite of the signals we have been conveying over the past years. The authorities are opting for a surprisingly short-sighted approach on such fundamental issues for the future of the nation. The longer the delay in tackling these issues, the more difficult and painful it will be to resolve them.

 

2.3.14. Policy on Innovation of Production Patterns

 

Active intersectoral restructuring has been taking place in Bulgaria over the last 50 years. The share of agriculture has been declining in favour of industry and services. The share of industry first stabilised and over the past 10-15 years started declining in favour of services.

This process will go on in the next 20 years. The share of agriculture and forestry will decline to 5-7% of GDP and of the work force by 2020. This will lead to a significant increase of productivity in the economy as a whole and in agriculture but will make redundant the majority of the employed in agriculture. The process will be active until 2015-2020 and will then decelerate.

Industry (mining, processing, power generation, gas, water and construction) will continue to lose its share both in production and in employment, to reach 22-24% by 2020.

The services sector will develop fastest and will absorb the workforce released from agriculture and industry. It may account for 69-71% of GDP by 2020 and will have a similar share in employment (see table 11.1)

Further intersectoral restructuring, particularly after EU accession, will cause problems that are not yet known to the public. The much lower labour productivity in Bulgarian agriculture compared to EU agriculture, the lower competitiveness of agricultural products, the lower sanitation and hygiene standards will cause a significant reduction of the employment in this sector. The production quotas that will be imposed on us within the Common Agricultural Policy framework will add to this deterioration. An estimated 500,000 people will be released of the 760,000 that are now employed in the agriculture. This may have harsh social consequences.

Accession will affect Bulgarian agriculture in many other ways, some of which will be very severe. Opinions are emerging in the Westeuropean scientific community in support of an agricultural specialisation of Southern, North-western and Eastern Europe. As a result our region is to be entrusted with the production of mass bulk products, mainly grain. This will have a negative impact on profitability and employment in Bulgarian agriculture.

It would hardly be reasonable to treat Bulgaria in the same manner as Poland, Slovakia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Estonia and Romania and force it to specialise in growing grain. Our climate is more appropriate for southern cultures, which provide higher employment and income. Bulgarian natural and climatic endowment (particularly in the southern part of the country) does not differ from these in Northern Greece, Central and Northern Italy, Northern Spain and Portugal.

The dynamics of production adjustment in the coming years will increasingly move from the intersectoral to the intrasectoral area. The structural changes within industry, services and agriculture will be the most intensive - sub-sectoral and product adjustments. The dynamics of intersectoral changes will slow down and the potential for intrasectoral adjustments will remain great, almost unlimited, particularly in product patterns.

These dynamic intrasectoral adjustments seem chaotic only on the surface. In actual fact they are precisely targeted and specific. The current sectoral and product specialisation in Bulgaria is the result of a destruction of the structural profile created during central planning and the CMEA. It was conducted through the destructive processes of the 1990s, which are continuing today. This is a focused destructive adjustment.

Nowadays Bulgaria produces and exports primitive low added value goods, which are capital intensive, energy intensive and unskilled labour intensive. Their content of skilled labour and high technology is very low. The share of high-tech products is insignificant. A very large part of Bulgarian exports (30-40%) consists of simple labour intensive goods of low added value, subcontracted by western companies to Bulgarian manufacturers – the so-called outsourcing. They are made with designs and materials of the customer using low cost labour and cheaper energy in Bulgaria.

The significant size of electricity exports is not a sign of a mature industrial structure either. The surplus of energy is temporary – owing to the stagnation of the Bulgarian economy.

As a future EU member Bulgaria must develop its sectoral, sub-sectoral and product profile. The question is whether the structural menu should be compiled based on the current sectors, sub-sectors and products with the respective comparative economic advantages. These sectors are low tech, resource intensive, energy intensive (with cheap energy) and labour intensive (with low salaries). In other words Bulgaria would confine itself to the framework of low-tech sectors and products. This may currently be an inevitable choice, due to the cheap energy and labour that generates some income, but will be wrong in the medium and particularly in the long-term.

Bulgaria has to make a great strategic move in the structural reorientation of its economy over the next 20 years. In view of the current and to a certain extent - the medium term realities Bulgaria will be forced to sustain its profile in low-tech operations by constantly renewing them with new products of medium, high and top level technology. The share of labour intensive low-tech goods can be reduced to some 15-20%, resource intensive low tech products  - to 15-20%, medium level technology products can be increased to 40-45% and high-tech products to about 20-25% by 2020 (see table 11.1.). This will be a very difficult structural transformation. It is, however, indispensable because no accelerated development is possible without it.

From the point of view of export efficiency, attention should be focused on producing more complex machines and installations, electromechanical and optical machines and installations, more complex transport machines and equipment, pharmaceuticals, ecologically clean agricultural products etc. Management of the companies will make the specific decisions on structural readjustment. They have to formulate their priorities independently. Any attempt of public authorities to impose them would be inappropriate.

The existing energy sector development strategy must be revised. It is not based on an overall long-term strategy for Bulgarian economic development and, therefore, on an estimate for future domestic energy consumption. Energy saving policy in the consuming sectors has not been incorporated in this strategy. No reliable investigations have been conducted on the long-term electricity needs in the neighbouring countries. The estimates of their future demand were a product of biased improvisation, used as an excuse by the parties interested in increasing power generation in Bulgaria at any cost.

In its current shape, the energy development strategy may have negative long-term effects, since it relies on a non-existent import demand on the part of neighbouring countries and possibly on an overestimated domestic demand. It is impossible to establish national energy needs not knowing how the economy and the household sector will develop over the coming decades.

The new energy strategy until 2020 must be based on a more economical use of energy in the business and the household sector, the development of gas distribution and supply, and environmentally appropriate methods of power generation. It is cheaper to focus on rationalising energy consumption rather than increasing power generation based on imported primary energy sources at unpredictable prices.

There are no sound economic arguments in favour of generating energy in Bulgaria for export. The official claims that Bulgaria is proud to be an energy centre on the Balkans are baseless. The huge investments for such a strategy can be used in a more rational way to develop other export oriented high tech industries. These would generate more value added and employment. One must choose among different technical and economic scenarios to this end.

Major structural readjustment is needed in the service sector. It is insufficient to state that the share of services will grow at the expense of agriculture and industry. The type of services to be developed is more important. The rapid growth of security services, the mushrooming parasite intermediary activities, the old-fashioned transport services, the abundance of primitive trade and restaurant services is a ground for concern. This is an evidence of the backward level of the services sector and unhealthy developments in the economy and society.

World experience demonstrates that it is more reasonable to develop modern services of the ICT-related type, modern healthcare, education, pre-school facilities and childcare. The same goes for research, other innovation activities, modern recreation facilities, services for the elderly, intensive tourism, financial intermediation, modern business services, protection of the environment etc. This is what the advanced European countries are doing.

There will be important adjustments with severe consequences in the geographic structure of business activities. As already stated, accelerated development will be the major focus for Bulgaria in the coming 20 years and beyond. High-speed growth can be generated mainly in regions and communities that offer favourable conditions – modern production capacities, telecommunications, transport, technical, social and other infrastructure, qualified personnel and market proximity.

The most intensive development in the coming years and decades will occur in the big cities – Sofia, Plovdiv, Varna, Bourgas, and other larger towns and will be least intensive in the small towns, in the villages, mountainous regions with poor infrastructure and human resources.

The regional divergence in Bulgaria will grow until 2020-2030. This is inevitable but policies can be initiated to mitigate the negative implications. This calls for partially compensating preventive measures by the authorities at both national and regional level. The Bulgarian public must be informed about this trend and be prepared to face the consequences!

The development of business activity in Bulgaria will depend also on the behaviour of foreign capital. If the latter abstains from establishing active production and business links with local enterprises there will be less scope for improvement of the structural profile of industry and services. As a result a dualistic economy may develop – with isolated enclaves of relative modernity at a few foreign enterprises, in an environment of mediocre business activities at the domestic companies.

This is why it is so important to attract first class foreign investors by means of privatisation, and not merely second and third ranked companies and even offshore and other unreliable participants with short-term interests. The quality of the new owners of privatised companies is of primary importance rather than the price received. If the current type of privatisation and the absence of first class foreign investors persist in the future Bulgaria will be impeded in modernising the structural profile of its economy. It is already significantly burdened by the wrong and even criminal privatisation carried out so far.

The European model is an important benchmark for structural updating of Bulgarian industry and services. It was proved a long time ago that the closer the sectoral and the product patterns of two economies, the greater the potential for stable specialisation and production co-operation between them. According to this indicator, Bulgaria, along with Romania, is in the least favourable position. Our sectoral pattern is very different from the average EU sectoral patterns. The patterns of the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia and Hungary are much closer to those of the EU countries.

Bulgaria has a restricted capacity to participate alone in the global production networks. The establishment of specialised and high-tech small and medium sized companies in the respective niches, together with foreign partners, will allow for a better quality, higher competitiveness and opportunities to become part of such networks. It would be good to create awareness of this now and to initiate preparations. A significant improvement of the education system is indispensable, along with the establishment of research and development facilities and the creation of a favourable economic and institutional environment for their operation. If preparations start now the results may become evident in 10-15 years.

Along with other favourable economic and social consequences such an approach may help thousands of qualified professionals to remain in Bulgaria and work in cutting edge technology areas instead of looking for them abroad in more difficult environment and less chances of success.

The analysis of the quality of Bulgarian exports to the EU confirms that the convergence potential is much more restricted and worrying than it looks from traditional quantitative indicators – a negative balance of trade and current account. The larger part of Bulgarian export is raw materials or primary processed low value-added goods, which do not generate sufficient revenue to the producers and the economy at large. Such export can not continue for long as it impedes accelerated development.

Reducing the current account deficit by increasing exports under these circumstances not only is very difficult, but its benefit is doubtful. The manufacturers compensate the loss from low export prices through cheap labour, cheap energy, illegal imports, not disclosing other turnover, tax- and social contributions evasion. Such business practices, in addition to being irrational, can not continue endlessly.

The intensity of intercompany restructuring will grow, as will restructuring by forming international strategic alliances and the intrasectoral exchange on the basis of sustained specialisation and production co-operation between Bulgarian and foreign companies.

 

2.3.15. Financial System Development and Resource Mobilisation

 

The development of the financial system is one of the priority areas of economic policy for attaining strategic goals. Its role in the study is considered with the view to creating prerequisites for mobilising resources for accelerated development. The emphasis is set on developing public finances and the banking system.

The main conclusions and recommendations for developing public finances are:

- A number of economic and political considerations and harmonisation agreements with the EU will have a strong impact on the scope, structure and sequencing of the development of public finances until 2010. After 2010 the level of fiscal harmonisation in general and taxation in particular in the EU will have a dominating impact. The major directions for their development are predetermined and national flexibility is constrained;

- Attention should focus on resolving a series of problems:

а) Reducing gradually redistribution of GDP through the budget;

b) Balancing the budget within a longer period of time - 15-20 years. Temporary deficits of 2-3% should be tolerated if justified;

c) Strengthening financial decentralisation and reforming the intrabudgetary relations;

d) Restructuring the revenue and expenditure parts of the budget according to the strategic goals and priorities of accelerated development;

e) Improving tax and other revenue collection and a more rational use of resources.

On the system of public spending:

-         Gradual reduction of public spending as a share of GDP. The speed will increase in the second decade;

-         Restructuring public expenditures with the aim of strengthening their incentives function and focusing on attaining strategic goals;

-         Aligning budget spending policies with efficiency principles. This is a prerequisite for rationalisation and higher efficiency of public spending;

-         Targeted unification of the multi-tiered budget system and creating spending tools and mechanisms for operations and control at the national, sectoral and regional levels;

-         Applying budget principles and methods of modern budget management that have been adopted in the EU.

On the tax system:

-         An enhanced process of tax harmonisation with the EU, incl. alignment of the tax systems, types and rates of various taxes;

-         Gradual reduction of the overall tax level and the tax burden;

-         Increasing the stimulating function of taxation;

-         Significant improvement of tax collection;

-         Continuing transfer of the tax burden from direct to indirect taxes;

-         On direct taxation: Gradual reduction of the rates of corporate taxation and personal income tax aiming at their unification. Applying tax relief including through the tax base. Co-ordination of the tax and social security contributions aiming at a reduction of the tax burden in real terms. Priority should be given to pro-active depreciation policies and introducing tax credit to promote investment, rather than reducing the rate of corporate taxation;

-         On indirect taxation. Gradual reduction of the uniform VAT rate, improving its organisation procedures and harmonisation with EU requirements. Some negative effects are expected from the accelerated harmonisation of specific excise duties.

The main conclusions and recommendations for developing the banking system and the other financial institutions are:

-         Financial services have a key and growing role for boosting economic development, particularly through combining financial with information and communication technologies;

-         In order to use the potential of the financial sector, interrelated policies and measures are needed aiming at two directions: first, to develop the banking system and the other financial institutions and second, to improve the environment for their operation. In order to ensure a better co-ordination between individual policies and their tools, a strategy for financial sector development must be elaborated as an integral part of the national economic development strategy by 2020. This strategy has to be in line with the EU trends in this area.

The main directions of the banking system and other financial institutions development policy have to be as follows:

-         Eliminating structural handicaps, expressed in the lacking diversity of financial and credit institutions;

-         Credit institutions development stimulating consolidation, control and improved efficiency;

-         Improving financial and credit institutions specialisation;

-         Establishing a nation-wide debtor information pool;

-         Adapting the national payments system to European standards;

-         Enhanced development of non-banking financial institutions - insurance companies, pension funds, venture capital funds etc.

The main focus of the policy on creating a favourable environment for the functioning of financial institutions should be:

-         Creating an economic environment by co-ordinating the policies and measures for economic restructuring and financial system development and elaborating effective mechanisms for making compromises on key issues;

-         Creating a legal framework supporting the development of an effective system of private property and mechanisms transforming property into production capital. The same applies to  adapting regulations and supervision to world-wide trends, European requirements, specific conditions in Bulgaria and new technologies in a timely manner;

-         Policies for capital market development aiming at increasing its role in the market infrastructure and facilitating private sector and public institutions access to investment resources. The same applies to reducing the monopoly power of banks in credit provision; achieving a lower cost of capital, higher investment and ultimately a higher speed of economic growth and competitiveness.

 

2.3.16. Institutional Policy

 

The inconsistencies in the choice of the approaches to institution building created additional difficulties when implementing key priorities of the transformation in the area of:

- Economic liberalisation in favour of the emerging commodities, services, capital and labour markets;

- Macroeconomic policies for modernising government regulation, for stabilisation of public finances and increasing the effectiveness of resource management by the national and local budgets;

- Making privatisation and corporate governance effective and restructuring enterprises with the aim of fostering economic modernisation.

An assessment of the situation and the main factors and areas of development of institutional policy was conducted within the accelerated development strategy.

The strategic choice of the approaches, goals and areas of institutional policies derives from the assumption that economic growth can be positively impacted by institutions provided they reflect the democratic choice of social change. It takes into account the link between institutions and markets of production factors.

Two basic issues have been analysed when assessing the initial preconditions for accelerated development of the Bulgarian economy: The first is the extent to which the development of formal and informal institutions can guarantee a regulation of the new markets and institutions that is adequate for public needs. The second deals with the possible future institutional development when competition will replace regulation and self-regulating institutions will become an inherent feature of organised markets.

The mechanisms and tools of the institutional structure for social and economic progress have been defined in a medium and long-term perspective.

The choice of priority goals and areas of the Bulgarian institutional policy depends on several key factors. Sustaining political democracy and developing a civil society, along with securing economic liberalisation and protecting competition in the newly emerged markets are the most important of them.

In the medium term a transition will take place from policies dominated by the national state to policies leading to restrictions on national sovereignty.

The long-term challenges that the Bulgarian State will face before achieving functional and institutional integrity with the EU as a full member are identified. In the optimistic scenario – Bulgarian EU membership in 2007 - this process will continue from 2007 to 2020. It will run effectively in parallel with institutional policy tasks related to the development of the EU single market, as well as the possible preparation for joining the Economic and Monetary Union.

Developing a national sovereignty of a modern type, by means of which the “accession” of Bulgaria to the global economy will take effect with institutional support, is considered as urgent in view of the need for solutions to common contemporary problems.

The choice of the priorities of institutional policy is evaluated according to various conceptual approaches. They are separated in three main groups: first, neoliberal approach; second, opposing the state and its role in the market economy; third, recognising globalisation and the new global order as a dominating factor for the institutional policy of the nation state. When formulating institutional policy special attention is devoted to the acknowledged socio-democratic minimum comprising two processes:

а/ Introduction of the opinion and the interests of the people into the political system;

b/ Guaranteeing government accountability to the public.

The comparison between the three approaches allows for the conclusion, that a democratically chosen regulatory institutional optimum will be necessary for the socio-economic development of Bulgaria. It should be combined with developing modern state governance and well performing institutions in the process of EU accession.

The strategic priorities and goals of institutional policy have been outlined. From the point of view of institutional change, overcoming the modernisation crisis marked with the absence of sustainable economic and social achievements and experience - becomes very important. Reconsidering Bulgarian experience should go along with the adoption of the best international and European practice.

The main mechanisms of institutional policy subject to our attention include:

-         achieving a stable balance and interaction between the legislative, executive and judiciary authorities for the benefit of an accelerated growth;

-         further consolidation and improving the efficiency of public finances and government;

-         aligning macroeconomic and structural policies aiming at accelerated social and economic development;

-         fighting corruption and opposing institutionalisation of corruption in the public and private sector through developing organised markets.

 

2.3.17. Economic Aspects of Environmental Policy

 

Adherence to environmental standards is achieved mainly by means of control and prohibitive measures. There is, however, a trend to replace them with economic tools and one can assume that they will dominate in the following years and decades.

The economic tools regulating the quantity of pollution leave it to the market to determine who should adapt and in what ways. They are most appropriate for situations where the regulator demands security for attaining environmental goals without specifying who must make the effort for reducing hazardous emissions. Pollution is ultimately reduced where that costs the least. The society will thus de-couple economic growth from environmental pressure in the cheapest possible manner.

The most frequently used tools for achieving environmental goals are taxes, pollution and consumer charges, insurance policies, tradable emission rights for polluters, etc. When they are used, the “polluter pays” principle applies.

A better idea of the full costs in terms of the cost of raw materials, energy, water, transportation and other services is given by including the external environmental effects. This, in turn, makes it possible to better evaluate their comparative efficiency. Subsidised prices of raw materials, fuel, water and transport services, without taking into account the environmental aspects, are misleading. One can not make proper decisions on the basis of these prices.

Environmentally sensitive pricing will change the traditional understanding of the efficiency of large production facilities. In the case of growing transportation cost one will have to explore technological and economic solutions to reduce the capacity of the individual production units and the enterprises and for ways to locate them closer to consumers or raw material sources.

This will facilitate the mitigation of environmental pressure, but will create other problems - changes in the geographic location of business activities and in employment, income, mobility, lifestyle. The traditional concepts for the development of the Rhodopi region, the Strandzha-Sakar region, the valley of the river Mesta etc, which depend 100% on road transport, will change. It may be necessary to revisit some current decisions to close down important (but non-profitable according to traditional criteria) railway lines in various regions of Bulgaria.

Incorporating external environmental effects in prices leads to a change in the composition of production, in employment, income and regional structures. The actual production costs can thereby be calculated and the businesses can select production patterns, which after allowing for full expenditures provide a higher environmentally sensitive growth for a long period of time. They contribute to an improvement in the quality of life of the people in the long-term.

Such approaches touch on economic, social, environmental and other interests of many people, of economic and social groups, and affect the competitiveness of many industries. Applying them without some compromises is, therefore impossible.

This becomes even more difficult if conducted only in one country and not in all countries that are business partners. Such an approach is only possible under concerted action of all interested countries and of the respective economic, social, regional and other interests in Bulgaria. If this is not done in a concerted manner by all interested states, the affected nations must be free to protect themselves by means of customs policies.

Subsidies for producing and consuming solid fuel should be abolished. The same applies for tax relief that has a negative environmental impact. In complex situations these changes have to be made gradually in co-ordination on a regional scale (between neighbouring countries) and even on a global scale. Such co-ordination is also needed when liberalising the energy market and introducing “green” tax reforms, because they have contradicting effects.

The high sensitivity of energy consumption to energy prices is an undisputed fact. The price of energy, however, should not be increased sharply. The sustainable policy of steady increase, conveyed to consumers in advance in order for them to prepare is the more acceptable option.

The prices for raw materials, fuel, energy, water and other commodities in short supply or commodities harmful to the environment are of great importance for their more sensible use. As stated above, these prices must reflect the direct production costs as well as all external costs (i.e. damage to the environment) and to incorporate some profit that secures normal current operations and investment for development.

This is all the more important for Bulgaria for at least two reasons: The energy intensity of production in Bulgaria is 4-5 times higher than in the EU-15 and in the CECs. The prices for electricity and heating in Bulgaria are far lower than in the EU and CECs.

Our assessments predict an alignment of energy prices in Bulgaria with the current price level in CECs by 2010 and with the current price level in Western Europe by 2015-2020. There will be a gradual increase of energy prices over the entire period until 2020 (see table 4.12). Unlike Western Europe, the liberalisation of energy market in Bulgaria under the present circumstances will not lead to a decline of energy prices.

The higher prices will play an important role in determining the environmental structure, will discipline energy consumption and will thus contribute to developing more rational economic patterns in the coming years and decades. This is very important due to the low energy efficiency of Bulgarian production.

It is advisable to regulate the quantity and quality of used water through pricing, taxation and charges. Bearing in mind that a modern agriculture with stable high yields is impossible in the Bulgarian climate without irrigation, subsidies for irrigation water are needed following the schemes applied in the southern member states of EU-15. Bulgaria must subsidise the water for irrigation for a duration and scale commensurate with the southern EU member states. Bulgarian authorities must not give in to the expected pressure of the European Commission to abolish or cut subsidies for irrigative agriculture.

The price of water for industrial, irrigation and household purposes must vary. The price of water for irrigation in agriculture should be the lowest and that for household purposes - the highest. In order to encourage saving water for industrial and irrigation purposes an additional charge may be introduced. The proceeds should be used for investment in captation, transportation, reducing waste and improving water quality.

The charge per cubic meter of water should reflect availability – if there is a higher shortage in a region the charge should be higher and vice versa. Moreover, charges may vary depending on the quantity of water used by consumers. Large consumers should pay higher additional charges than the small ones.

Pesticides and chemical fertilisers are the largest pollutants of soil and water. In view of this, one can include a charge in their sale prices. One can thereby facilitate the reduction of soil and water pollution as well as the moderate use of chemical fertilisers and pesticides, which may have a harmful effect on human health. This will encourage the production of environmentally friendly agricultural produce.

The European Commission, along with the International Commission for Danube Research and Monitoring are drafting a Joint Programme for use and protection of the water in these 800,000 square kilometres sized river basin with a population of 82 million. Bulgaria is likely to be a pro-active participant in this programme.

A wider application of charges is recommended for solid waste deposited in landfills in order to encourage its separate collection and recycling. The approach toward enterprises that have large amounts of solid waste should differ from the one toward households. There should be special (higher) charges for particularly harmful and hazardous waste along with the generally applicable solid waste charges.

Compulsory waste recycling should be introduced, including such for complex machines and equipment – cars, computers, electric machinery, locomotives and other transport vehicles, tractors and other agricultural machinery and household appliances. The producers of waste should, according to the “polluter pays” principle, be the first to conduct this. Recycling cost can be incorporated in the prices of new items which become waste after their use.

Environmental protection requires large investment. Forecasts on the investment needed in Bulgaria to meat the EU environmental standards are scarce and those available should be used with caution. There are no reliable assessments in Bulgaria. According to western forecasts Bulgarian investment needs vary from 10 to 15 billion Euro. This assumes allocations of 4-6% of GDP over a period of 20 years. Such a task is impossible to accomplish! Based on the 0.7% of GDP allocated for environmental expenditure in 2000, we asses investments amounting to 2.5-3.5% of GDP by 2010 and 4.0-4.5% by 2020. (see table 4.12).

Environmental criteria are becoming very important for all future investments. Each investment project, regardless of its purpose, should first be evaluated from the point of view of environmental advisability and only then on other criteria. If a project is not environmentally acceptable it should not be adopted even if it was economically sound. Environmental considerations should become the most important criterion for future investment decision making.

Table of Contents

 

 

Annex

 

Table of Contents

of the full text, published in Bulgarian

 

Foreword. Prof. Ivan Angelov

 

Part One. Accelerated Development – Substance, Necessity, Sources and Objectives

Chapter I. Necessity and Opportunities for Accelerated Development in Bulgaria. Prof. Ivan Angelov

Chapter II. Converging Economic Development – Theory and Practice. Prof. Ivan Angelov

2.1. Indicators for the Level of Economic Development and Convergence

2.2. Economic Growth and Converging Development - Basic Notions and Theories

2.3. Long-term Global and European Trends of Convergence (Divergence)

2.4. Trends for Convergence (Divergence) among CEECs

2.5. Trends for Convergence (Divergence) among Regions in the EU and CEECs

2.6. Driving Forces of Growth and Convergence

2.7. Transmission Mechanism for Growth and Convergence

2.8. Conclusions

Chapter III. Substance, Principles, Functions and Content of the Strategy for Accelerated Development. Prof. Ivan Angelov

3.1. Development as a Transformation of Society

3.2. Principles and Functions of the Strategy for Accelerated Development

3.3. Components of the Strategy for Accelerated Development

3.4. Conclusions

Chapter IV. Objectives of the Strategy for Accelerated Development. Prof. Ivan Angelov

4.1. Overall Characteristic of the Objectives

4.2. Specific Objectives of Accelerated Development

4.2.1. GDP per Capita

4.2.2. Economic Objectives

4.2.3. Social Objectives

4.2.4. Environmental Objectives

4.3 Conclusions

Chapter V. Sources of Economic Growth. Prof. Ivan Angelov

5.1. Utilisation of Manpower and Economic Growth

5.2. Labour Productivity and Economic Growth

5.3. Total Factor Productivity and Economic Growth

5.4. Composition of the Sources of Economic Growth

5.5. Conclusions

 

Part Two. Economic Policy Priorities for the Achievement of Strategic Objectives

Chapter VI. Transmission Mechanisms from Economic Policy to Economic Growth

6.1. The International Experience. Prof. Ivan Angelov

6.2. Modelling Economic Growth in Bulgaria. Dr. Paraskeva Dimitrova

Chapter VII. Appropriate Economic Environment

7.1. Policy for Macroeconomic Stability. Prof. Ivan Angelov

7.2. Regulation, Deregulation, Competition and Entrepreneurship. Prof. Ivan Angelov

7.3. Foreign Economic Policy. Stefan Uzunov

Chapter VIII. Policy for Saving and Investment in Physical and Human Capital

8.1. Savings Policy and Investing in Physical Capital. Prof. Ivan Angelov

8.2. Policy of Investing in Human Capital. Dr. Matiu Matev

Chapter IX. Socio-Economic Policy

9.1. Employment and Unemployment Policy. Dr. Goran Bankov

9.2. Income Policy and Living Standard. Dr. Goran Bankov

9.3. Alleviation of Negative Implications of the Demographic Crisis. Prof. Ivan Angelov

9.4. Mitigation of Social Polarisation and Alienation. Prof. Ivan Angelov

Chapter X. Economic Aspects of Science and Technology Policy. Prof. Ivan Angelov

10.1. Economic Aspects of Innovation Policy.

10.2. Economic Policy for the Promotion of break-through Science and Technology Developments.

Chapter XI. Economic Aspects of Structural Adjustment Policy. Prof. Ivan Angelov

11.1. Modernisation of Consumption and Production Patterns.

11.2. Adjustments of Consumer Patterns and Consumption Policy.

11.3. Adjustments of Production Patterns

Chapter XII. Financial System Development and Mobilisation of Resources. Dr. Ivanka Kraininska

12.1. Development of Public Finances

12.2. Development of the Banking System and other Financial Institutions

Chapter XIII. Institutional Policy. Dr. Tatiana Hubenova-Delisivkova

13.1. Strategic Choices of the Approaches and Objectives of Institutional Policy

13.2. Important Mechanisms of Institutional Policy

13.3. Instruments of Institutional Policy

Chapter XIV. Application of Economic Tools for Environmental Objectives. Prof. Ivan Angelov

14.1. Necessity of Economic Tools

14.2. Reducing Climate Change and Energy Utilisation

14.3. Reducing Utilisation, Quality Upgrading and Reduction of Losses of Water

14.4. Reduction and More Rational Utilisation of Fossils and Liquid Waste

14.5. Investments for Environmental Protection

 

Executive Summary - Conclusions and Recommendations

 

References

Table of Contents

 



[1] All references to tables refer to the full text in Bulgarian.